Skatteudvalget 2021-22
SAU Alm.del
Offentligt
2629819_0001.png
IMF
NOTES
Taxing Windfall Profits in the
Energy Sector
Thomas Baunsgaard and Nate Vernon
NOTE/2022/002
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0002.png
©2022 International Monetary Fund
Taxing Windfall Profits in the Energy Sector
NOTE/2022/002
Thomas Baunsgaard and Nate Vernon*
DISCLAIMER:
The IMF Notes Series aims to quickly disseminate succinct IMF analysis on critical economic
issues to member countries and the broader policy community. The views expressed in IMF Notes are
those of the author(s), although they do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, or its Executive
Board, or its management.
RECOMMENDED CITATION:
Baunsgaard, Thomas and Nate Vernon. 2022. “Taxing Windfall Profits in the
Energy Sector” IMF Note 2022/00X, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
ISBN:
979-8-40021-873-6 (Paper)
979-8-40021-877-4 (ePub)
979-8-40021-881-1 (PDF)
Q31; Q35; Q38; Q48; H21; H25
Natural resource taxation; extractive industries; progressivity; windfall
taxation; economic rents
[email protected]
[email protected]
JEL Classification Numbers:
Keywords:
Authors’ email addresses:
*
The authors are grateful to Alexander Klemm, Mario Mansour, Ruud de Mooij, Ian Parry, James Roaf and other colleagues
for very helpful comments and suggestions.
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0003.png
Taxing Windfall Profits in the Energy Sector
Thomas Baunsgaard and Nate Vernon
August 2022
Commodity prices for coal, oil, and natural gas have increased sharply during 2022, although prices have
retreated somewhat more recently. The increase stems from a combination of factors, including a mismatch
between energy demand and supply during the economic recovery from COVID-19, further amplified by the
Russian war in Ukraine.
The surge in fossil fuel prices has generated substantial windfall profits in the energy sector. This has
benefited mainly firms that extract fossil fuels, but, in some cases, profits have increased elsewhere in the
energy sector, such as for oil refineries and renewable-energy-based electricity generators. Meanwhile,
countries face fiscal pressures to support the post-COVID economic recovery and alleviate the strain on
vulnerable households and firms arising from the high energy prices. Looming over all of this is the need to
contain inflation, maintain energy security, and transition to renewable energy.
This raises a key tax policy question: whether and, if so, how to tax windfall profits realized by energy
companies. The answer is particular to each country and energy segment, but the following guidelines are
recommended:
Introduce a permanent tax on windfall profits from fossil fuel extraction, if an adequate fiscal instrument
is not already in place. The tax should be imposed on a share of economic rents (that is, excess profits)
because rent-targeting taxes raise revenue without reducing investment or increasing inflation.
Economic rents generally arise from fossil fuel extraction as a result of the fixed supply and diverse
quality of natural resource deposits, rather than from other segments of the energy value chain.
Use caution when it comes to temporary taxes on windfall profits: these tend to increase investor risk,
may be more distortionary (especially if poorly designed or timed), and do not provide revenue benefits
above those of a permanent tax on economic rents. Investors prefer a stable, predictable tax regime
over the risk of future temporary taxes when prices rise.
Encourage the switch to renewable energy, given the need for decarbonization in energy generation. It
is counterintuitive to introduce exceptional taxes on renewable energy-based electricity generation,
especially if these are poorly designed. Such taxes may deter future investment by increasing investor
perception of risk. Moreover, transitioning to renewable energy improves energy security.
Still, apply the following design principles if political pressure makes it necessary to tax windfall profits
from electricity generation: The tax should apply to a clear measure of excess profit (for example, profit
above a specified return on capital) that avoids arbitrary references to specific price levels or time
periods. The tax should not apply to revenue (as this can be inflationary and is more likely to reduce
investment). The tax should allow for carryforward of losses to ensure symmetrical treatment of losses
and profits. The tax can be permanent if excess profits are expected to be persistent.
Consider future reforms to market mechanisms that may unnecessarily result in windfall profits for
electricity generators and fossil fuel refiners. For example, electricity generators may earn windfall
profits because of the design of electricity tariffs or because market access is restricted.
IMF
|
Note
NOTE/2022/002
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0004.png
Introduction
Fossil fuel prices have surged during 2022, boosting profits for many energy companies but also
increasing pressure on households and businesses.
The need to raise revenue to support fiscal measures
to alleviate the associated pressure from higher fuel prices has sparked renewed policy interest in the taxation
of windfall profits in the energy sector, and some countries have introduced exceptional tax measures in
response. This note provides guidance for policymakers on options for taxing windfall profits and presents an
overview of the current practice for taxing windfall profits—or more generally, economic rents—originating from
the extraction of fossil fuels.
The extraction of natural resources, such as minerals and petroleum, has the potential to generate
economic rents.
1
Economic rents may materialize when a factor of production is in limited supply, for natural
resources reflecting the fixity of resource endowments and the diverse quality of deposits (see Boadway and
Keen in Daniel and others 2010). Rents are commonly considered to originate at the upstream point of
extraction, whereas mid- and downstream segments are more akin to processing and transportation activities.
Economic rents are commonly defined as the return on an investment above the minimum threshold needed for
the investment to be undertaken, with both location-specific (reflecting geological and cost differences across
projects) and cyclical components (reflecting changes over time in demand or supply).
2
A well-designed tax on
economic rents can therefore provide government with additional revenue from more profitable projects without
distorting investment and production decisions.
Windfall profits in the case of natural resources can be inseparable from the cyclical component of
economic rents.
It is intuitive that windfall profits arise from an unanticipated event unaffected by the actions or
decisions of an investor. An obvious example is a surge in commodity prices benefiting a project after an
investment decision has been made. The fact that realized profits turn out to be higher than anticipated at the
time of the investment decision comes down partly to luck. In practice, there is no easy way to distinguish
between windfall profits arising from commodity price surges and underlying economic rents.
3
However, a tax
system designed to capture a portion of economic rents effectively taxes windfall profits as well.
Fossil fuel prices have increased significantly since the Russian invasion of Ukraine.
This has amplified
the price rebound associated with the economic recovery from COVID-19 and reduced fossil fuel investment,
partly because of adjustments in anticipation of the energy transition and increasing competitiveness of low-
carbon alternatives (Figure 1). The increase in commodity prices is driving higher profits in fossil fuel-producing
countries and extractive companies (see Annexes 1 and 2). Natural gas prices have increased most sharply in
Europe, which in turn has driven up electricity prices.
This note is structured as follows:
The next section provides policy guidance for taxing windfall profits arising
from fossil fuel extraction and extends this guidance to address instances in which windfall profits may originate
temporarily from other segments of the energy sector. The subsequent section gives an overview and analysis
of current petroleum fiscal regimes and existing fiscal mechanisms aimed at capturing a portion of the economic
This note focuses on fossil fuels, although the principles generally carry over to minerals—some fiscal instruments, however, such as
production sharing, are not common in the mining sector.
There may also be firm-specific rents (for example, arising from a patent or from know-how). For extractive industries, these tend to be
smaller than location-specific rents, although there are clearly cases in which new technology enables innovative companies initially to earn
high returns.
In theory, windfall profits can be defined as profits from commodity prices exceeding their expected price over the course of an investment.
Practically, it is difficult to design a policy that targets such profits, since the size of profits depends on investor-specific assumptions (for
example, the expected commodity price). More important, a policy targeting windfall profits does not provide advantages over those
targeting economic rents.
3
2
1
IMF
|
Note
2
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0005.png
rents. This also provides an overview of recent tax measures targeting the energy sector more broadly in some
European countries.
Figure 1. Fossil Fuel and Electricity Price Indices
2. Electricity prices, since 2020
1. Fossil fuel prices, since 2019
Source: IMF, Primary Commodity Prices database. Note: prices
are through the end of July 2022.
Source: Statista, US Bureau of Labor Statistics, UK Ofgem. Note:
prices are through the end of June 2022.
Tax Policy Advice
Natural resource tax policy design should generally consider efficiency, ease of collection, equity, and
revenue-raising ability.
Taxes on economic rents are efficient since they do not reduce investment (because
the tax applies only to returns above what is required to invest) and can raise substantial revenue in sectors with
persistent rents. They can also foster a sense of fairness by ensuring that more profitable projects pay more tax.
In contrast, ordinary corporate income taxes apply to both rents and the normal return on (equity) investment, so
they can reduce investment/supply but not as much as taxes on production (for example, royalties), which do
not consider a firm’s costs.
Tax policy advice should be tailored to different stages in the energy value chain.
The key reason is that
economic rents generally originate from extraction activities (that is, upstream) rather than from fossil fuel
processing, distribution, and retailing and electricity generation (see Annex 2 for information on producer
profits).
4
However, there may also be instances of temporary windfall profits generated by mid- and downstream
companies that benefit from fossil fuel price increases (for example, low-carbon electricity producers with sales
at the market price, rather than at a fixed price).
Taxing Windfall Profits from Upstream Extraction
It is best practice to include a fiscal instrument targeting economic rents in the fiscal regime for natural
resource upstream extraction.
This will complement other fiscal instruments that provide relatively more
certain and stable revenue (for example, royalties and corporate income tax) and will, in principle, take effect
only when a project realizes economic rents (See Daniel and others 2010 and Wen 2018 for a fuller discussion).
In countries that rely more on rent-targeting fiscal instruments, fiscal revenue may be more volatile, which in turn
4
The economic rationale is that location-specific rents lead to excess profits for lower-cost producers and from commodity price surges
benefiting primarily producers.
IMF
|
Note
3
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0006.png
requires a macro-fiscal framework for revenue management that saves a higher share of windfall revenue gains
to promote intergenerational equity from an exhaustible and nonrenewable resource.
There is a menu of options for rent-sharing fiscal instruments differing in how well they target rents.
A
tax that applies to project cash flow after a minimum investment return has been realized is the least distortive,
but its more precise targeting often requires a more complex design that can complicate revenue administration.
Common rent-sharing instruments are listed below in the order of how well each targets rents.
Cumulative-rate-of-return-based cash flow tax: This tax is assessed on the cash flow generated by a project
and will apply only after a minimum “normal” rate of return (either before or after corporate income tax) has
been realized. In doing so, it taxes only the excess return on the investment. This neutrality is in practice
achieved by uplifting the negative cash flow by the threshold rate of return (in principle, a similar effect could
be achieved by refunding the tax value of losses when cash flows are negative, although this would
increase the risk to the government if an investment is unsuccessful). The tax is ring-fenced at the project
level to effectively target the rents generated by the investment. The tax can be more challenging to
administer and requires transition rules if introduced after project development has begun.
Project-level tax with uplift on capital expenditure: This is a simpler variant of the rate-of-return-based tax
designed by applying a percentage uplift to qualifying capital expenditure over a specified time period. This
ensures that the minimum return on investment is not taxed.
R-factor–based progressive profit oil sharing: This is a common design in production-sharing contracts
5
whereby the profit-oil sharing follows a progressive rate structure linked to the ratio between cumulative net
revenue and investment (the so-called R-factor); when the R-factor exceeds one, the investment cost has
been recouped. The R-factor does not directly measure rents because it does not incorporate the time value
of money, but this can be approximated by setting the bottom R-factor threshold above one.
A supplementary tax on corporate profits when a certain profitability threshold is met: This is relatively easy
to apply and does not require ring-fencing at the project level but is not as well targeted at rents. The
targeting at windfall profits by the supplementary tax could be further refined by a progressive rate structure
linked to a measure of profitability (for example, return on assets) or proxied by commodity prices.
A variable royalty rate linked to commodity prices: This is easy to apply but is less well targeted at economic
rents and can reduce supply since the tax increases the variable cost of production.
Country-level decisions on the appropriate rent-capturing instrument should balance the ability to target
rents versus the administrative complexity
(Table 1). Taxes that are less well targeted at rents, such as
variable royalty rates or taxes imposed at the corporate level, could diminish supply increases in response to
rising prices and deter new investment. Administrative complexity may be binding in underresourced and low-
capacity tax administrations—if this is the case, improving capacity should be prioritized since it is crucial to
implementing an efficient fiscal regime, but the immediate tax policy responses may assume existing capacity
constraints. In addition, the ease of a progressive instrument’s application to existing projects should be
considered: some tax designs require complex transitional rules and access to project-level information on past
costs and revenue or may be constrained by contracts’ existing fiscal stability clauses.
Production-sharing contracts set out fiscal and operational responsibilities for oil and gas investors and are common, especially in
developing countries. The investor (that is, the contractor) receives a share of production to recover costs, while production allocated to
profit is shared between the investor and the government.
5
IMF
|
Note
4
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0007.png
Table 1. Overview of Rent-Targeting Fiscal Instruments Applied to Fossil Fuel Extraction
Tax type
Cumulative-rate-of-
return-based cash
flow tax
Project-level tax
with uplift on capital
expenditure
R-factor–based
progressive “profit
oil” sharing
Supplementary tax
rate on corporate
profits
Variable royalty
rate linked to
commodity prices
Ability to target rents
High,
taxes only rents (i.e., investment-neutral) if
the uplift rate is at or above the investor’s required
return. The cash flow tax delays payments until
rent is realized, making it slightly more efficient
than the uplift-on-capital-expenditure option
Medium,
the R-factor does not take into account
the time value of money so is not a direct
measure of rents and makes setting the minimum
threshold more difficult
Low to medium,
loss-making and non-extraction
activities remove a portion of project-level rents
from the tax base
Low,
does not take into account the project’s cost
structure and increases the variable cost of
production so can trigger early project cutoff
Administrative complexity
Medium,
requires oversight
and auditing of project-level
revenues and costs; uplift
rate is contentious. The uplift-
on-capital-expenditure option
requires determination of
which capital cost categories
qualify for uplift
Low,
calculated and audited
using existing corporate
income tax return information
Low,
calculated and audited
using existing royalty
information
Scope
Project level,
difficult
to apply to existing
projects
Project level,
more
easily applied to
existing projects
Project level,
difficult
to apply to existing
projects
Corporate level,
applies to existing
projects
Project level,
easy to
apply to existing
projects
It is best to have a rent-targeting instrument in the fiscal regime from the beginning rather than
introducing new taxes after a natural resource investment has been made.
This allows a potential investor
to assess the impact of the tax under varying profitability assumptions before reaching an investment decision.
An intriguing argument in favor of rent-taxing instruments is that they give investors more certainty ex ante: the
more progressive fiscal regime reduces political pressure on the government to subsequently introduce ad hoc
fiscal instruments if a windfall profit materializes.
Many fossil-fuel-producing countries already have a progressive instrument that captures a portion of
the economic rents generated by a commodity price surge.
For these countries (especially those with
relatively high effective tax rates) it makes little sense to introduce fiscal regime changes in response to a short-
term price surge—see the next section on country practices for examples of countries with progressive
instruments and high effective tax rates.
The trickier question is how countries without a rent-targeting mechanism should respond to an event
that leads to windfall profits.
Faced with a surge in commodity prices, perhaps expected to be transient rather
than permanent, policymakers understandably may consider introducing an exceptional temporary tax measure.
But a temporary tax measure can be distortionary and increase investor uncertainty, especially if the tax is not
well targeted at rents or if the timing of its introduction or removal is ill-judged. In addition, to counteract the
negative impact on investor uncertainty, there may be pressure to include generous investment incentives in
temporary windfall taxes (for example, the UK energy profit levy, with an 80 percent investment allowance)—
such policies could promote short-term investment in the fossil fuel sector since the tax benefit of investment in
extractives is relatively high.
A better response for countries with room in their existing fiscal regime is a permanent, well-designed
rent-targeting mechanism.
This determination is country-specific and should take into account both the overall
level of taxation in the upstream sector and its response to changes in profitability.
6
The fossil fuel industry will
still play an important role in the transition to a carbon-free energy future, and the increased certainty a well-
designed progressive tax provides may promote long-term investment, including in transitional fuels such as
natural gas.
In addition, in many countries, fiscal stability clauses in contracts may also limit the impact of policy changes on existing projects; these are
not, however, relevant for large advanced producers (for example, Norway, United Kingdom, United States).
6
IMF
|
Note
5
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0008.png
Fiscal regime design should also prioritize reducing direct greenhouse gas emissions from fossil fuel
production (commonly called Scope 1 emissions).
A mixture of regulatory and price measures can be used
to incentivize a switch to less emitting production methods and reservoirs during the energy transition.
7
The
case of Norway illustrates how a carbon and methane tax can be integrated into a petroleum fiscal regime while
still achieving an overall high level of progressivity without discouraging investment (see section on country
practices for more).
Windfall profits are likely concentrated in specific fossil fuel-producing countries rather than in
importers.
This may lead to political pressure in countries that are net importers of fossil fuel or where large
energy multinationals are headquartered to seek to capture rents generated in producing countries, partly as a
way to finance support for affected households and firms. However, there are few tax policy options for taxing
fossil fuel imports that do not further drive up consumer prices.
8
Tax Policy Advice for Electricity Generators and Refineries
Increases in pump prices are the visible sign of a commodity price surge, but significant rents usually
do not originate from petroleum refining and distribution.
However, there can be instances in which
demand and supply imbalances in the petroleum product value chain can lead to temporary windfall profits. An
example is the current constraints in petroleum refinery capacity in the United States and some other countries,
which has led to a surge in refiner profits, known as the “crack spread” between the price of crude oil and
wholesale fuel products (especially diesel). A comparison of the increase in the tax-free pump price with the
increase in the relevant international oil price indicates that mid- and downstream companies are receiving a
portion of the windfall, under the assumption that non-crude oil business cost increases do not fully offset the
increase in spreads (see
Error! Reference source not found.
for an analysis of the United States and
European countries). In many other countries, pump prices are regulated, further strengthening the argument for
focusing rent-targeting mechanisms on the upstream segment.
In addition, electricity producers with fixed cost structures may profit as electricity prices increase.
In
Europe higher natural gas prices have pushed up electricity tariffs, providing windfalls to renewable and nuclear
power electricity producers and fossil fuel-based electricity producers with contractually fixed natural gas and
coal purchase prices. Although profitable companies will pay more in corporate income tax, some EU countries
have introduced temporary taxes in response; these are, nevertheless, somewhat arbitrary (discussed in the
next section).
The political pressure to raise revenue from segments of the energy sector that may enjoy temporary
windfalls is understandable, but the case for rent-targeting taxes in the electricity sector is not strong.
At a time when the key priority should be to incentivize energy diversification away from fossil fuels, the
signaling effect of a tax targeting renewable energy producers is especially mixed. Introducing a temporary
windfall profit tax reduces future investment because prospective investors will internalize the likelihood of
potential taxes when making investment decisions. Moreover, in many cases, taxes in response to price surges
may suffer from design problems—given their expedited and political nature. This exacerbates the harm to
investment and could curtail existing supplies—for instance, taxes on gross revenue are especially distortive
and can exacerbate inflation if they increase marginal costs for a large set of suppliers.
7
See Baunsgaard and Vernon (forthcoming) for an analysis of emission taxes on fossil fuel producers.
In general, it is less persuasive to introduce additional taxes on imports to seek to capture rents; it has been argued, however, in the
context of the European Union, that import tariffs can be targeted at extracting monopoly rents on Russian oil exports and could provide a
strong incentive to diversify the energy mix (Gros 2022).
8
IMF
|
Note
6
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0009.png
Box 1. Comparison of Increased Pre-tax Retail Prices and Crude Oil Prices
Tax-free retail prices have increased by more than international oil prices in the United States and some
European countries, indicating that mid- and/or downstream companies are receiving a portion of
windfalls from oil price increases.
Spreads, which are defined as the difference between the crude oil prices
and gasoline/diesel retail prices, excluding taxes, have increased relatively more in the United States than in the
average European country and more for diesel than for gasoline (Figure 2). However, there is significant variation
across countries in Europe. In some there has been a decrease in spreads; in others the increase has been
higher than in the United States. The average increase in spreads is quite large: gasoline spreads are currently
~$0.15 per liter (~65 percent) higher in Europe and the United States than the 2019 average, while diesel spreads
are $0.15 per liter higher in Europe (56 percent) and $0.34 per liter higher in the United States (112 percent).
Figure 2. Gasoline and Diesel Price Spreads
1. Gasoline Price Spreads
2. Diesel Price Spreads
Sources: EU Oil Price Bulletin; US Bureau of Labor Statistics; US Energy Information Administration; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Spreads are adjusted for inflation. Brent and West Texas Intermediate oil prices are assumed as the international benchmark for European
countries and the United States, respectively.
There is evidence that increases in spreads result in higher refinery profits.
For example, recent analysis
from the US Energy Information Administration (EIA) finds that refinery profits increased substantially across all
regions within the United States in 2021 relative to 2020 and are above or near 10-year highs (EIA 2022a), while
other EIA analysis shows that crack spreads were also elevated in Europe and Singapore in recent months (EIA
2022b).
A confluence of temporary events has resulted in higher spreads for refineries.
These factors include (1)
reduced refining utilization and petroleum product export quotas in China, (2) reduced supply of Russian
petroleum products due to sanctions, (3) reduced US capacity due to some refineries shutting down, (4) inelastic
refining supply since refineries are operating near capacity and it takes time to build new capacity, and (5)
increased demand for petroleum products from the COVID recovery (EIA 2022b). In all, this allows operating
refineries to increase prices, but markets should eventually rebalance and return to pre-COVID conditions.
If there are indeed economic rents consistently earned by electricity generators and oil refiners,
policymakers should identify and remedy the root cause.
For electricity generation, the windfall profits are
at least partly a by-product of the design of the electricity tariff-setting mechanism. It may therefore seem more
fruitful to focus on how to strengthen the tariff-setting mechanism if temporary windfall gains by some electricity
producers are viewed as a disadvantage.
An excess profits tax on such companies could, nonetheless, provide a backstop against future windfall
profits.
An argument can also be made for a more permanent excess profits tax that applies more generally, as
discussed in Hebous, Prihardini, and Vernon (forthcoming). As with a tax that targets economic rents in the
IMF
|
Note
7
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0010.png
extractive sector, such a tax should apply to a clear, well-defined measure of excess profits (for example, the
return on capital above a specified level), allow for carryforward of losses, and avoid parameters that reference
a particular time period or price level. These design characteristics are desirable since they should avoid
distorting investment decisions by taxing only profits above the cost of capital and avoid the need for ad hoc
adjustments to the tax rates or parameters as market conditions change.
Country Practices
Fiscal Instruments Targeting Economic Rents or Windfall Profits
Many countries with fossil fuel extraction already have an instrument in their upstream fiscal regime
targeting economic rents either with a flat or variable rate structure.
Examples include Norway (special
petroleum tax), progressive R-factor–based production sharing (for example, common in many developing
countries), and rate-of-return-based fiscal instruments (for example, Angola and Australia). A few countries have
tax rates for either income taxes or royalties that vary with commodity prices (for example, Canada, Nigeria,
Trinidad and Tobago) or additional taxes on the sector (for example, the supplementary charge and the recently
introduced energy profits levy in the United Kingdom). In contrast, other countries have fiscal regimes that are
less responsive to surges in profits; for example, the United States.
9
Table 2 provides examples of several
countries’ rent-targeting fiscal instruments.
Table 2. Petroleum Fiscal Instruments Targeting Economic Rents
Source: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) database.
Note: Immediate expensing of capital expenditure (rather than depreciation) ensures that the investor recovers its capital costs prior to
paying tax and reduces the likelihood that the tax system will distort investment decisions. Interest deductions are uncommon for rent-
targeting taxes because the investor generally receives an allowance for the cost of debt and equity financing through either an uplift on
losses or capital costs or having a relatively high profitability threshold to trigger the payment of tax. Capex = capital expenditure ; CIT =
corporate income tax; IRR = internal rate of return; LTBR = long-term bond rate; NA = not applicable; PSC = production-sharing contract; R
= R-factor, DROP = daily rate of production. 1) Parameters for the rent-targeting mechanisms vary by contract. 2) The law changed in 2019
9
Several competing tax reform proposals attempting to capture windfalls from the petroleum sector have been put forward in the United
States (see Matheson 2022 for an assessment of the proposals). However, at this stage none of these proposals have moved forward.
IMF
|
Note
8
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
to reduce the uplift amount and adjust time limits on uplift levels. 3) Called a “special participation fee.” An additional deduction is provided
based on the DROP so that the tax base approximates excess profit. Decrees set forth the parameters. 4) Applies only to oil sands. The
"royalty" is 1 percent–9 percent on gross revenue prior to the project recovering costs and then 25 percent–40 percent of net cash flow with
adjustments. 5) Uplift on eligible investment is 62.5 percent for the 10 percent supplementary charge and 80 percent for the 25 percent
energy profits levy.
Some European countries have introduced or announced new taxes or other fiscal mechanisms in
recent months on a temporary basis to capture windfall profits.
These apply in one case to fossil fuel
extraction (United Kingdom) but, otherwise, target the electricity sector. In most cases, the revenue from
temporary tax measures is earmarked for expenditure measures to soften the consumer impact of higher energy
costs.
Greece: Imposed a 90 percent levy on windfall profits of domestic power producers for the period October
2021–March 2022.
Hungary: Announced a temporary windfall tax for 2022 and 2023 on “extra profits” from energy companies
(as well as other sectors with different tax rates). In the energy sector, the tax applies on revenue generated
from the difference between world market oil prices and actual prices paid on imports of oil products from
Russia with a 40% tax rate (the rate was 25% until the end of July 2022).
Italy: Introduced a one-time 25 percent tax on energy companies (producers and sellers of electricity,
natural gas, and petroleum products). The tax applies to company profits that rose more than €5 million
between October 2021 and April 2022 compared with the same period in the previous year.
Spain: Announced a temporary windfall profits tax for extraordinary profits earned in 2022 and 2023 by
electricity utility companies.
Romania: Introduced an 80 percent windfall profits tax on additional revenue realized by electricity
producers calculated on the monthly difference between the average selling price and 450 lei per megawatt
hour. The tax was subsequently modified to apply to net revenue, taking account of costs. The government
also adjusted the fiscal regime for natural gas, introducing a progressive tax of 15 percent to 70 percent on
additional income on gas prices above 85 lei (about $18) per megawatt hour.
United Kingdom: The energy profits levy, introduced in July 2022 and set to expire by the end of 2025, is an
additional 25 percent tax on oil and gas profits on top of the existing taxes, taking the combined rate to 65
percent. Previous losses or decommissioning expenditure cannot be offset against profits subject to the
levy. To encourage new investment, there is an additional 80 percent investment allowance. The levy does
not apply to electricity generation.
The European Commission also issued guidance on the design of temporary windfall profits tax
measures that would apply to electricity generators (EC 2022, Annex 2).
The guidance sets out a number
of requirements for such taxes, including a requirement that taxes be temporary, preserve market signals (that
is, not increase marginal costs), discriminate based on generation technology, and use clear and verifiable
criteria for determining “excessive” rents.
Evaluating the Responsiveness of Petroleum Fiscal Regimes to Changes in Profits
When evaluating the sharing of project cash flow between the investor and the government, there
should be a focus on the entire fiscal regime.
This makes it possible to capture the interaction between
different fiscal instruments (for example, rent-targeting taxes, royalties, production sharing, profit taxes, state
participation, and so forth). The Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) framework (IMF 2022) is
designed to support such analysis and is used in the following paragraphs to analyze the fiscal regimes of large
producers. See Annex 3 for a detailed description of the modeled fiscal regimes.
The level and composition of the government take vary significantly across oil and gas producing
countries
(Error!
Reference source not found.3).
Average effective tax rates (AETRs) for a selected group of
large producers range from 35 to 90 percent, with lower AETRs resulting in a greater share of project profits for
IMF
|
Note
9
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0012.png
investors. The variation in AETRs is driven both by the baseline level of tax rates for more common taxes, such
as royalties and the corporate income tax, and by whether a tax system has mechanisms directly targeting
economic rents (for example, Norway’s Special Petroleum Tax and Australia’s Resource Rent Tax), significant
equity participation (for example, Algeria), or royalty rates that increase with prices (for example, Saudi Arabia).
Jurisdictions with AETRs above 70 to 80 percent when prices are high (for example, Norway and Saudi Arabia)
collect a large portion of project profits and have no basis for imposing new taxes in response to windfalls. This
is not true of countries with AETRs (far) below 70 percent (for example, Mexico, United States, and United
Kingdom before introduction of the energy profits levy), most of which do not have robust rent-targeting
mechanisms in their fiscal regime. The analysis also shows that the introduction of the temporary energy profits
levy makes the United Kingdom petroleum fiscal regime less of an outlier.
Figure 3. Average Effective Tax Rate
1. Low price ($60 per barrel)
2. High price ($110 per barrel)
Sources: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) model; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Production sharing relying on mechanisms not related to economic rents, such as production rates and corporate income tax, is
categorized as “profit/income-based.” The “other” classification includes primarily taxes on pollution, such as carbon taxes, and
withholding taxes. Norway does not require its state-owned oil and gas company, Equinor, to take an ownership stake in new licenses,
but Equinor participates in numerous production licenses as a majority or minority partner. EPL = excess profits levy; PSC = production-
sharing contractor.
The extent to which the government’s take responds to changing price levels also varies
(Error!
Reference source not found.4).
Countries relying more on profit-based fiscal mechanisms have relatively
stable AETRs across different profitability outcomes since the tax base (and sometimes the tax rate) grows as
prices increase, while fiscal regimes with higher royalties and no excess profit taxation have declining AETRs
because pretax profit grows faster than the tax base. Fiscal regimes including a progressive instrument result in
more stable outcomes as prices change and greater certainty for investors due to reduced political pressure to
introduce discretionary changes to taxes when prices are high. Norway is an outlier in that it has both a
progressive regime and a high AETR. Others have either modest AETRs but adequate progressivity (Australia)
or low AETRs and/or regressive fiscal regimes (the US government take is particularly low and regressive). In
addition to rent-targeting tax or price-based royalties, Algeria, Norway, and Saudi Arabia also increase
progressively through large, fully paid equity stakes in oil and gas projects.
IMF
|
Note
10
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0013.png
Figure 4. Progressivity, AETR across Price Levels
Sources: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) model; and IMF staff calculations.
The short-term response of government revenue
to a negative or positive price shock across
countries generally mimics that of progressivity.
10
A higher short-term response (that is, higher
elasticity) means that the government takes on a
larger portion of short-term commodity price risk
(Figure 5). Fiscal regimes with profit-based
mechanisms tend to have larger immediate changes
to revenue (for example, Algeria and Norway) since
the price change feeds directly through to changes in
the tax base; royalties and indirect taxes are not as
responsive because the tax base change is less
pronounced
11
and the price change may not be large
enough to trigger a new royalty rate threshold.
Figure 5. Elasticity of Government Revenue
Sources: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) model;
and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Assumes a 20 percent price increase and decrease. EPL =
excess profits levy; PSC = production-sharing contractor.
10
The elasticity metric measures the one-year change in revenue for a given project that has recouped its initial investment, as compared
with the progressivity analysis, which assess the level and evolution of effective tax rates over the life of an entire resource project (that is
during the exploration, development, production, and decommissioning phases).
A numerical example is provided to show how the change in commodity prices impacts the tax base of royalties and profit-based taxes.
Prior to the price increase, revenue is $10, costs are $6, and profit is $4. The price increases by 50 percent, resulting in revenue of $15 and
profit of $9, meaning that the profit tax base increases by more than 100 percent (as it goes from $4 to $9), whereas the royalty base
increases by only 50 percent (as it goes from $10 to $15).
11
IMF
|
Note
11
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0014.png
The breakeven price is a measure of whether a fiscal regime distorts investment decisions
(Figure 6).
Taxes that are independent of profit levels generally
Figure 6. Breakeven Price
result in higher breakeven prices because they apply
regardless of the project’s underlying profit—some
examples include carbon taxes (in Norway and
Canada) and royalties (in most countries)—but taxes
targeting economic rents are not distortionary and,
thus, should not prevent investment. For example,
although Norway’s AETR is far higher than that of
offshore US projects (~85 percent compared with 40
percent), the breakeven price is only $5 per barrel
higher since Norway’s excess profits tax increases
the government’s take when prices are high but
Sources: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) model; and
imposes only a small (or no) burden on projects that
IMF staff calculations.
are less profitable as a result of lower commodity
Note: investor minimum return is assumed to be 13 percent in real terms.
prices or higher project costs.
The project has the same pre-tax return across fiscal regimes to isolate the
 
impact of the fiscal regime on the breakeven price. In reality, the underlying
project production and cost structure vary significantly. EPL = excess profits
levy; PSC = production-sharing contractor.
IMF
|
Note
12
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0015.png
Annex 1. Windfalls by Country
Methodology
The country-level impact of recent oil, gas, and coal price increases is estimated at an aggregate level
both for energy consumers (that is, households, firms, and government) and for producers.
The impact on producers is estimated using the following steps:
(1) Production remains at 2019 levels (the
most recent year of comprehensive data from the International Energy Agency World Energy Balances), except
in the case of Russia, for which production is adjusted down to reflect reduced sales. (2) Producer prices
increase by the difference between the average price from March 2021 to July 2022 and the average price for
2019 for the portion of production that is exported, while domestically consumed production is valued at the
change in domestic retail prices—the discount between Urals oil and Brent oil is applied to Russian exports. The
increase in government revenue from taxing producers is also estimated using average effective tax rates for a
country fuel pair, calculated in the IMF Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) model (or the world
average if data are missing) using country-specific fiscal models.
A similar methodology is used for consumer impact:
(1) Consumption remains at 2019 levels. (2) Consumer
prices are observed or (if data are not available) estimated using the historical relationship between international
fossil fuel price changes and retail prices (Amaglobeli and others 2022).
Windfalls for largest producers
Combined gains for producers and governments of several large fossil fuel producers exceed 10
percent of GDP (Annex
Table 1.1); gains are generally largest for natural gas producers, especially those that
sell into European markets, since European natural gas prices have increased more than those of coal and oil.
The gain to producers and government offsets the consumer loss in almost all cases (with the exception of
India).
Annex Table 1.1. Producer, Government, and Consumer Impacts of International Price Increases
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: government revenue is included as a gain. If the extractive company (that is, the investor) is a state-owned company, all gains
effectively go to the government, but this is ignored due to a lack of data on such companies.
IMF
|
Note
13
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0016.png
Annex 2. International Oil Company Profits
The largest oil and gas companies experienced increased profitability in the first quarter of 2022, with
indications that the upstream segment drove profit (Annex
Error! Reference source not found.2.1). Across
major petroleum companies, the return on equity and net income for the first quarter of 2022 far exceeded that
of the previous four years, illustrating that the negative impact of impairments of assets in Russia was more than
offset by higher oil and gas prices. The profit increase appears to have been driven by extraction activities, at
least until the second quarter of 2022—for example ExxonMobil, Chevron, and Eni saw a three- to fivefold
increase in upstream profits in late 2021 and early 2022 (FT 2022a; Chevron 2022a; Eni 2022a). In the second
quarter of 2022, refining and downstream sales contributed more to total profits than in the previous quarter, but
exploration and production activities still drove profit increases (ExxonMobil 2022; Chevron 2022b; Eni 2022b).
Annex Figure 2.1. Large Oil and Gas Company Profitability
1. Return on equity (percent)
2. Net income, quarterly average (billions of US dollars)
Source: S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Saudi Aramco has been excluded from the net income chart due to very high income ($10 to $39 billion quarterly average in each
year). PetroChina and Saudi Aramco had not reported their second quarter 2022 earnings at the time of the analysis.
IMF
|
Note
14
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0017.png
Annex 3. Fiscal Regimes for Comparator Countries
Annex
Error! Reference source not found.3.1
provides the main mechanisms and parameters for the fiscal
regimes modeled above.
The full structure of the fiscal regime and interactions between individual
mechanisms are important because they ultimately determine the government take and the impact of fiscal
policy on investment decisions—in other words, looking only at the progressive (or distortive) elements can
result in misleading assessments. Note that the modeled regimes may not reflect the most recent structure, as
they are intended to capture the design applicable to most existing projects (for example, the Nigeria 1993
production-sharing contract and Saudi Arabia 2017 concessions are modeled, rather than the 2021 Petroleum
Industry Bill and updated royalty rates, respectively).
All modeled countries apply corporate income tax to the extractive sector, while there is mixed use of
royalties and rent-targeting taxes.
Seven countries have royalties, with rates ranging from five to 50 percent,
and three countries have royalty rates that vary with commodity prices (Canada, Mexico, Saudi Arabia). Seven
countries also have rent-targeting taxes, but with varying designs—three allow for additional deductions to
capital (Norway) or all expenses (Brazil and Kazakhstan), two are cash flow taxes with uplift on losses (Australia
and Russia), Algeria has a tax rate increasing with the R-factor, and the United Kingdom provides a surcharge
on the corporate income tax base but without a deduction for interest. Five countries have significant equity
interests, all of which are assumed to pay their share of exploration costs (although conclusive information is not
available for Algeria and Kazakhstan).
Annex Table 3.1. Modeled Oil and Gas Fiscal Regimes
Source: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) library.
Note: DB = declining balance; DROP = daily rate of production; EPL = excess profits levy; NA = not applicable; prod. = production; PSC =
production-sharing contractor; SL = straight line.
1
Royalties are reduced by 50 percent for domestic sales. There is an additional export tax of 0–32 percent depending on the oil price.
2
Includes the 15 percent branch profit tax.
3
A non-price-based component of the royalty is biddable and assumed to be 10 percent. The Mexican regime reflects that of the 2017 bid
round 2.4.
4
There are multiple regimes in Russia. The latest regime with the adoption of the resource rent tax (called the AIT) is modeled.
IMF
|
Note
15
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0018.png
Source: IMF, Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI) library.
Note: DROP = daily rate of production; DWT = dividend withholding tax; EPL = excess profits levy; IRR = internal rate of return; IWT =
interest withholding tax; NA = not applicable; PSC = production-sharing contract; SWT = state withholding tax; USD = US dollar
1
Value-added tax is not included as all modeled countries are assumed to provide timely refunds on exports and not exempt major business
inputs.
2
Withholding tax rates represent the lowest available rates provided through a country's tax treaties.
3
CO2 eq = carbon dioxide equivalent with methane converted to CO2 equivalent using a 100-year time horizon.
4
Applies only to nonresident subcontractors in most cases.
IMF
|
Note
16
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0019.png
References
Amaglobeli, David, Emine Hanedar, Gee Hee Hong, and Céline Thévenot. 2022. “Fiscal Policy for Mitigating the
Social Impact of High Energy and Food Prices.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Baunsgaard, Thomas and Nate Vernon. Forthcoming. “Tax Policy for Fossil Fuel Production in Support of
Climate Change Mitigation.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Chevron. 2022a. “Chevron Announces First Quarter 2022 Results.”
https://www.chevron.com/-
/media/chevron/stories/documents/1Q22-earnings-press-release.pdf.
Chevron. 2022b. “Chevron Announces Second Quarter 2022 Results.”
https://www.chevron.com/-
/media/chevron/stories/documents/2Q22-earnings-press-release.pdf.
Daniel, Philip, Michael Keen, and Charles P. McPherson, eds. 2010.
The Taxation of Petroleum and Minerals:
Principles, Problems and Practice.
Routledge Explorations in Environmental Economics. New York:
Routledge/International Monetary Fund.
European Commission (EC). 2022. “Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the
European Council, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and The Committee of the
Regions.” Brussels.
https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=COM%3A2022%3A108%3AFIN.
Eni. 2022a. “Eni: Fourth Quarter and Full Year 2021 Results.”
https://www.eni.com/assets/documents/press-
release/migrated/2022-en/02/eni-fourth-quarter-2021-ceo-claudio-descalzi-comments-results.pdf.
Eni. 2022b. “Eni: Results for the Second Quarter and Half Year 2022.”
https://www.eni.com/assets/documents/press-release/migrated/2022-en/07/eni-second-quarter-2022-ceo-
claudio-descalzi-comments-results.pdf.
ExxonMobil. 2022. “ExxonMobil Announces Second-Quarter 2022 Results.”
https://corporate.exxonmobil.com/-
/media/Global/Files/investor-relations/quarterly-earnings/earnings-announcements/2022-earnings-
announcements/2q-earnings-release.pdf.
Financial Times
(FT). 2022a. “ExxonMobil Flags Highest Quarterly Profit since Boom Year of 2008,” April 4.
https://www.ft.com/content/7b92387d-c39f-4f9b-be3f-5d806831b5d7.
Financial Times
(FT). 2022b. “When the Windfall Blows,” May 24.
https://www.ft.com/content/7228c193-b848-
4c95-943a-bf1b29460c68.
Gros, Daniel. 2022. “The Smartest EU Sanction on Russia,” March 18.
https://www.project-
Resyndicate.org/commentary/eu-impose-special-import-tariff-on-russian-gas-and-oil-by-daniel-gros-2022-
03?barrier=accesspaylog.
Hebous, Shafik, and Alexander Klemm. 2018 “A Destination-Based Allowance for Corporate Equity.”
https://www.imf.org/-/media/Files/Publications/WP/2018/wp18239.ashx.
Hebous, Shafik, Dinar Prihardini, and Nate Vernon. Forthcoming. “Excess Profit Taxes: Historical Perspective
and Contemporary Relevance.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2022. “Fiscal Analysis of Resource Industries (FARI).” Washington, DC.
https://www.imf.org/en/Topics/fiscal-policies/fiscal-analysis-of-resource-industries.
IMF
|
Note
17
SAU, Alm.del - 2021-22 - Endeligt svar på spørgsmål 764: Spm. om, hvilke lande, der har indført såkaldte windfall taxes (særskat på overnormal profit) som følge af de høje prisstigninger, til skatteministeren
2629819_0020.png
Matheson, Thornton. 2022. “How Should the US Tax Petroleum Profits?” Tax Policy Center, Washington, DC.
https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/taxvox/how-should-us-tax-petroleum-profits.
US Energy Information Administration (EIA). 2022a, “Financial Review of the Global Oil and Natural Gas
Industry: 2021.” Washington, DC.
https://www.eia.gov/finance/review/pdf/finance_2021.pdf.
US Energy Information Administration (EIA). 2022b. “Short-Term Energy Outlook: May 2022.” Washington, DC.
https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/steo/archives/may22.pdf.
Wen, Jean-Francois. 2018. “Progressive Taxation of Extractive Resources as Second-Best Optimal Policy.”
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2018/06/13/Progressive-Taxation-of-Extractive-Resources-
as-Second-Best-Optimal-Policy-45923.
IMF
|
Note
18