Skatteudvalget 2016-17
SAU Alm.del Bilag 3
Offentligt
1671173_0001.png
Economic Policy Reforms
Going for Growth
INTERIM REPORT
2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0003.png
Economic Policy Reforms
2016
GOING FOR GROWTH
INTERIM REPORT
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0004.png
This work is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. The
opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official
views of OECD member countries.
This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or
sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries
and to the name of any territory, city or area.
Please cite this publication as:
OECD (2016),
Economic Policy Reforms 2016: Going for Growth Interim Report,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2016-en
ISBN 978-92-64-25007-9 (print)
ISBN 978-92-64-25008-6 (PDF)
ISBN 978-92-64-25130-4 (epub)
Series: Economic Policy Reforms
ISSN 1813-2715 (print)
ISSN 1813-2723 (online)
The statistical data for Israel are supplied 3by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use
of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli
settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
Photo credits:
Cover © Alain Jacoby-Koaly pour Studio Pykha
Corrigenda to OECD publications may be found on line at:
www.oecd.org/about/publishing/corrigenda.htm.
© OECD 2016
You can copy, download or print OECD content for your own use, and you can include excerpts from OECD publications, databases and
multimedia products in your own documents, presentations, blogs, websites and teaching materials, provided that suitable
acknowledgement of OECD as source and copyright owner is given. All requests for public or commercial use and translation rights should
be submitted to
[email protected].
Requests for permission to photocopy portions of this material for public or commercial use shall be
addressed directly to the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC) at
[email protected]
or the Centre français d’exploitation du droit de copie (CFC)
at
[email protected].
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0005.png
Going for Growth
was launched in 2005 as a new form of structural surveillance
complementing the OECD’s long-standing country and sector-specific surveys. In line with
the OECD’s 1960 founding Convention, the aim is to help promote vigorous sustainable
economic growth and improve the well-being of OECD citizens.
This surveillance is based on a systematic and in-depth analysis of structural policies and
their outcomes across OECD members, relying on a set of internationally comparable and
regularly updated policy indicators with a well-established link to performance. Using these
indicators, alongside the expertise of OECD committees and staff, policy priorities and
recommendations are derived for each member and, since the 2011 issue, six key
non-member economies with which the OECD works closely (Brazil, China, India, Indonesia,
Russian Federation and South Africa). From one issue to the next,
Going for Growth
follows
up on these recommendations and priorities evolve, not least as a result of governments
taking action on the identified policy priorities.
Underpinning this type of benchmarking is the observation that drawing lessons from
mutual success and failure is a powerful avenue for progress. While allowance should be
made for genuine differences in social preferences across OECD members, the uniqueness of
national circumstances should not serve to justify inefficient policies.
In gauging performance, the focus is on GDP per capita, productivity and employment. As
highlighted in the past and again in this issue, this leaves out some important dimensions
of well-being. For this reason,
Going for Growth
regularly features thematic chapters
dedicated to these other dimensions, and increasingly looks at the side effects of
growth-enhancing priorities on other government policy objectives.
Going for Growth
is the fruit of a joint effort across a large number of OECD Departments.
www.oecd.org/economics/goingforgrowth
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0006.png
EDITORIAL RESTORING HEALTHY GROWTH: POLICIES FOR HIGHER AND MORE INCLUSIVE PRODUCTIVITY
Editorial
Restoring healthy growth: policies for higher
and more inclusive productivity
pickup in global growth remains elusive, almost eight years after the financial crisis
erupted. The recovery in advanced economies is still muted, particularly in the euro area
and Japan, while growth has slowed in emerging-market economies (EMEs). Trade and
investment remain weak, while jobs and wage growth have been disappointing. Financial
markets are increasingly volatile as capital searches for both yield and safety. Getting back
to healthy and inclusive growth calls for urgent policy response, drawing on monetary,
fiscal, and structural policies working
together:
On the one hand, demand policies alone will
not restore sustainable growth; but on the other hand, policies to strengthen competition
and innovation, spur job creation, and repair financial systems to fund investment will
only yield results if there is enough demand.
This 2016
Going for Growth
report underscores the importance of synergies among
policies in designing policy packages. Policy coherence across a broad range of reform
objectives such as product market competition, labour mobility and financial market
robustness is critical to create an environment conducive to innovation and resource
reallocation, which are crucial to reverse the widespread slowdown in productivity and the
rise in inequality.
Productivity – a central ingredient in the pursuit of wellbeing – has been decelerating
in a vast majority of countries, with the slowdown going back to around 2000, at least in
advanced economies. While this may partly reflect measurement issues, a common set of
unsettling trends lie behind the aggregate slowdown: the dispersion of productivity growth
across firms within industries, the decline in the growth rate of investment in knowledge-
based capital, and the reduction in the pace of business creation. These trends are
outcomes from problems in the basic policy environment – market competition and
innovation, labour market institutions, financial structure and robustness – which also
contribute to unfavourable trends in income distribution.
In addressing the productivity and inclusiveness challenges, governments need to
keep in mind the basic policies that underpin these developments, and hence the need for
coherent policy packages. Start with narrowing the productivity gap across firms, which
requires a better diffusion of innovations from leading to lagging firms. Since leading firms
are mostly multinationals, the intensity of cross-border connections via trade, FDI, global
value chains and the mobility of skilled labour is crucial for the diffusion of knowledge and
technologies from these globalised “frontier” firms to national firms.
Giving international trade a fresh boost requires that recent multilateral agreements in
this area be forcefully implemented but also that efforts be made to further reduce barriers
in the form foreign ownership restrictions or preferential treatments of domestic suppliers
A
4
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0007.png
EDITORIAL RESTORING HEALTHY GROWTH: POLICIES FOR HIGHER AND MORE INCLUSIVE PRODUCTIVITY
with respect to public procurement, taxes and subsidies. In several EMEs – notably Brazil,
India and Indonesia – barriers to infrastructure investment need to be addressed to
significantly improve the transport and logistic services that underpin cross-border trade.
Next, consider improving knowledge diffusion and making the most of new
technologies, which necessitates synergic investments by lagging firms in various forms of
knowledge-based capital such as R&D, skills and organisational know-how. Despite the
need to revive investment in knowledge-based capital, the incidence of innovation policy
reforms appears to have steadily fallen in recent years, as documented in this report.
Furthermore, for reforms in the area of innovation to pay off, firms need the right
incentives to strive for the development of new and better-quality products at lower costs.
Strong product market competition provides such incentive. In this regard, the decline in
business start-ups in advanced economies could be a sign that barriers to entry, including
through the financial system, have been creeping up and hence that the strength of
competition is eroding.
Re-examination is needed of competition policy, bankruptcy legislation and product
market regulations to facilitate entry and exit, and to provide a level playing field between
new firms and incumbents. As emphasised in this report, pro-competition reforms are
particularly needed in services where the scope for both job creation
and
productivity gains
remains large. This is especially true for Germany, Japan and Korea where the gap in
productivity between services and manufacturing is the largest among advanced
economies, but also for China as the economy goes through a challenging rebalancing from
manufacturing to services.
Deeper global integration and the growing reliance on intangible forms of capital
stresses the importance of collective policy approaches in the areas of competition law
enforcement, regulatory harmonisation, basic research and the taxation of mobile capital.
One major achievement in 2015 has been the global agreement on a list of measures to
limit tax avoidance by multinationals through the so-called Base Erosion and Profit
Shifting (BEPS) action plan elaborated under the auspices of the G20 and the OECD.
In addition to fostering competition, product market reforms also facilitate the
reallocation of resources from low- to high-productivity firms. The efficiency of resource
allocation would be further enhanced with measures to reduce barriers to labour mobility,
notably those linked to housing markets. In turn, to ensure that resource reallocation truly
serves wellbeing, workers need to be better equipped and offered real opportunities to
adapt skills. Adult learning programmes should thus focus more strongly on skills
complementarity with technological progress so as to help to reduce skills mismatch and
to facilitate adaptation to the rapid change in the nature of tasks associated with specific
jobs. Improving the matching of skills to jobs raises productivity and reduces inequality.
Sustained growth and job creation are the best ways to improve income distribution,
since the low- income and less-skilled bear the brunt of economic downturns. A challenge
for several advanced economies – in particular those facing persistently high unemployment
such as France, Italy and Spain – is to shift social protection from specific jobs to individuals
so as to better support the process of jobs and firms turnover that underpins dynamic,
growing economies. Reforms in this area will help to improve job opportunities for youth and
low-skilled workers, particularly hard hit by unemployment. For emerging economies,
stronger social protection is needed to reduce informality and inequality, while fostering
domestic consumption.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
5
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0008.png
EDITORIAL RESTORING HEALTHY GROWTH: POLICIES FOR HIGHER AND MORE INCLUSIVE PRODUCTIVITY
Strong employment growth is critical to ensure that growth benefits all segments of
society, but it is not sufficient. In several countries, a large and rising share of the growth
benefits have accrued to high-income households, while income at the bottom has been
stagnant for many years. In the United Kingdom and in particular the United States, reforms
to provide better access to high-quality education for students from disadvantaged
backgrounds combined with measures to make the tax system more efficient and equitable
would help to make growth more inclusive. In some countries such as Italy and Korea,
household income has not kept up with GDP gains over the past two decades. Chapter 3 of
this report explores the channels through which the income generated through GDP is
transmitted to households.
Given the breadth and evolving nature of the growth and inclusiveness challenges
facing advanced and emerging economies, the slowdown in the pace of structural reform
documented in this report is deeply concerning. While the pace of reform should be
accelerating to restore sustainable and equitable growth, the pace of reforms appears to
have steadily declined since 2011-12. While some countries have made considerable
efforts, many have taken very little action and countries with ambitious reform
programmes, such as in India, Japan and Turkey face significant political challenges and
the risk of losing momentum. Progress has been made on the G20 action plan to raise
reform efforts, but much remains to be fully implemented.
Given the weak demand environment, structural reform packages that promote
productivity should focus as well in design on maximising short-run growth gains. Chapter
2 of this report reviews the issues and evidence on the impact of reforms introduced in a
difficult economic conjuncture for their outcomes in terms of both productivity and
income distribution. Reform strategies that put more weight on shifting the composition of
public spending towards investment, facilitating the entry of new firms in services, and
reducing barriers to labour mobility are most likely to boost activity in the short term, with
the support of demand policies and a repaired financial sector. More vigorous reform
efforts from euro area countries with a large current account surplus would also help to
ensure that the current growth pick-up in that region does not succumb to internal
divisions and external headwinds. All countries contributing collectively to reform efforts
and to supportive demand improves the prospects for a return to higher productivity and
more inclusive growth both at home and in the global economy.
Catherine L. Mann
OECD Chief Economist
6
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0009.png
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Table of contents
Executive summary
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Chapter 1.
Overview of structural reforms in the policy areas identified
as priorities for growth
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Overview of structural reforms in the policy areas identified
as priorities for growth. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
A global overview of the progress on reform priorities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Assessment of reform progress by country groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The implications of growth-enhancing structural reforms for inclusive growth
and macroeconomic rebalancing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Chapter 2.
Reform priorities in a difficult macro context.
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Reform priorities in a difficult macro context . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
11
15
16
17
19
22
55
59
60
63
64
Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65
Structural reforms in normal times . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Structural reforms under weak demand conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
Structural reforms under weak demand and constrained macroeconomic policies 73
Notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Appendix 2.1.
Detailed analysis on the impact of reforms in normal times . . . . . . .
77
78
82
Chapter 3.
From GDP to average household income: A look at the transmission
channels.
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
87
From GDP to average household income: A look at the transmission channels . . . 88
Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Adjusted Household Disposable Income: definition and cross-country patterns . . . 90
Tracking income growth from the household perspective and explaining
the gap
vis-à-vis
GDP growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
Income distribution between the household and non-household sectors . . . . . . . 99
From functional income distribution to income inequality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
Notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
Appendix 3.1.
Policy drivers of the labour share: a brief literature overview. . . . . . . 116
Chapter 4.
Structural policy indicators
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
7
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0010.png
Follow OECD Publications on:
http://twitter.com/OECD_Pubs
http://www.facebook.com/OECDPublications
http://www.linkedin.com/groups/OECD-Publications-4645871
http://www.youtube.com/oecdilibrary
OECD
Alerts
http://www.oecd.org/oecddirect/
This book has...
A service that delivers Excel
®
files from the printed page!
StatLinks2
Look for the
StatLinks2at
the bottom of the tables or graphs in this book.
To download the matching Excel® spreadsheet, just type the link into your
Internet browser, starting with the
http://dx.doi.org
prefix, or click on the link from
the e-book edition.
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0011.png
ISO CODES
ISO Codes
T
AUS
AUT
BEL
BRA
CAN
CHE
CHL
CHN
CZE
DEU
DNK
ESP
EST
FIN
FRA
GBR
GRC
HUN
IDN
IND
IRL
he codes for country names and currencies used in this volume are those attributed
to them by the International Organization for Standardization (ISO).
Country code
Country name
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Brazil
Canada
Switzerland
Chile
China
Czech Republic
Germany
Denmark
Spain
Estonia
Finland
France
United Kingdom
Greece
Hungary
Indonesia
India
Ireland
Currency code
AUD
EUR
EUR
BRL
CAD
CHF
CLP
CNY
CZK
EUR
DKK
EUR
EUR
EUR
EUR
GBP
EUR
HUF
IDR
INR
EUR
Country code
ISL
ISR
ITA
JPN
KOR
LUX
LVA
MEX
NLD
NOR
NZL
POL
PRT
RUS
SVK
SVN
SWE
TUR
USA
ZAF
Country name
Iceland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Republic of Korea
Luxembourg
Latvia
Mexico
Netherlands
Norway
New Zealand
Poland
Portugal
Russian Federation
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Sweden
Turkey
United States
South Africa
Currency code
ISK
ILS
EUR
JPY
KRW
EUR
LVL
MXN
EUR
NOK
NZD
PLN
EUR
RUB
SKK
EUR
SEK
TRL
USD
ZAR
Note:
EU refers to the average of 21 European Union members of the OECD.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
9
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0013.png
Economic Policy Reforms 2016
Going for Growth Interim Report
© OECD 2016
Executive summary
G
lobal growth prospects remain clouded in the near term, with emerging-market
economies losing steam, world trade slowing down and the recovery in advanced
economies being dragged down by persistently weak investment. These near-term
concerns arise against the background of a widespread deceleration of productivity gains,
with the downward trend going back to early 2000s – at least in advanced economies – and
with little signs of revival. The growth slowdown observed among emerging-market
economies over the past couple of years also raises questions about their capacity to
further closing the income gap vis-à-vis most advanced countries. The case for structural
reforms, combined with supporting demand policies, remains strong to sustainably lift
productivity and the job creation that will promote improvements in equity.
Going for Growth
offers a comprehensive assessment to help governments reflect on how
policy reforms might affect their citizens’ wellbeing and to design policy packages that best
meet their objectives. The
Going for Growth
framework is instrumental in helping G20
countries to monitor their efforts to fulfil the pledge made in 2014 of boosting their combined
gross domestic product (GDP) by 2%, and to adapt their growth strategies accordingly.
This interim report reviews the main growth challenges faced by OECD and selected
non-OECD countries and takes stock of progress over the past year or so in adopting
structural policy reforms to address them (Chapter 1). This is examined in light of the
thrust of the country-specific priorities identified in the 2015 issue of
Going for Growth.
The
potential implications of growth-enhancing reforms for inclusiveness and macroeconomic
rebalancing are also discussed, with a focus on public finance consolidation, the narrowing
of current account imbalances, and the reduction of income inequality.
The report also reviews the issues and evidence on the impact of reforms implemented
in a context of persistently weak demand as well as under different cases regarding the
availability or effectiveness of macroeconomic policies in supporting the reforms
(Chapter 2). Finally, the report provides an assessment of the link between income generated
from GDP and income distributed to households (Chapter 3). In particular, it examines how
the main channels through which GDP growth is transmitted to the household sector have
evolved over the past two decades across OECD countries.
Policy reform challenges
In devising reform strategies to sustainably improve the wellbeing of a majority of
citizens, governments around the world need to address deep structural weaknesses
that the crisis laid bare, but which in many cases originated well before.
The global slowdown in productivity growth has been characterised by the widening of
the dispersion of productivity growth across firms within industries, in particular
11
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0014.png
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
between frontier firms – essentially multinational enterprises which have maintained
steady productivity growth – and all other firms that operate well within the productivity
frontier. Removing barriers that stifle entrepreneurship and limit the capacity of firms to
make the most of knowledge and technological diffusion is a reform priority.
Reducing unemployment continues to be a major challenge for many countries, particularly
so in Southern and Central European countries where long-term unemployment remains
particularly high. Other countries have been facing relatively high rates of labour market
withdrawals (e.g. United States), low labour force participation of women (Korea and Japan)
or a high incidence of informal employment (most emerging-market economies).
Addressing these labour market challenges is a priority to make growth more inclusive.
Progress achieved in 2015
Even though progress is made in tackling some of the main challenges, the slowdown in
the pace of reforms observed in 2013-14 has continued in 2015, even after taking into
account measures that are in the pipeline but that have yet to be fully implemented.
The pace of reforms has varied both across countries and policy areas.
It continues to be generally higher in Southern European countries (in particular Italy
and Spain) than among Northern European countries. Outside Europe, countries where
a relatively high number of measures related to
Going for Growth
recommendations have
been taken include Japan among advanced economies, and China, India and Mexico in
the case of emerging economies.
Relatively more actions have been taken to lift the labour force participation of women
and to improve educational outcomes, while fewer actions are observed in the areas of
innovation policy, public sector efficiency or product and labour market regulation.
In countries where income inequality is a particular concern, the majority of actions
taken on policy priorities are likely to help narrowing the income distribution. However,
recent actions taken to boost growth are unlikely to help countries with largest current
account deficits to narrow their external imbalances.
Reforming in a context of weak demand
Against the background of subdued global economic prospects, there is a good case for
prioritising reforms that in addition to stimulate employment and productivity, can best
support activity in the short term.
Aside from raising investment in public infrastructure, these include reductions of
barriers to entry in services sectors with pent-up demand, reforms of benefit
entitlements in the areas of health and pension, as well as reforms of housing policies
and job-search assistance programmes to facilitate geographic and job mobility.
Increasing the short-term payoff from structural reforms also requires that remaining
financial sector dysfunctions be addressed so as to improve the flow of credit to
households and firms with limited access to financial markets.
In the euro area, a greater synchronisation of reforms would also help reduce the
transition costs by giving greater scope to monetary policy to mitigate the potential
rise in real interest rates resulting from persistently low inflation.
12
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0015.png
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Countries with very limited budgetary room may have to prioritise on high short-term
returns or on low-cost measures and ensure that others are financed through means
that are as friendly as possible to employment and growth.
GDP growth and aggregate household income
Real GDP has tended to grow by more than real household income in the majority of
OECD countries between the mid-1990s and 2013.
This growth gap is partly due to factors having little policy traction, in particular the fact
that consumption prices (which include VAT) have tended to rise relative to production
prices over the period under consideration, the only exceptions being commodity
exporters such as Norway, Australia and Canada.
The household income share of GDP, simply defined as the ratio of nominal household
disposable income over nominal GDP, has been stable over the period under
consideration and on average across OECD countries. This average stability masks
heterogeneity in both the level and evolution across countries, with a large decline
observed in Austria and Korea and a large increase in the Slovak Republic and Finland.
Developments in the household income share of GDP can be assessed by looking at the
profile of households’ labour, capital and secondary ( i.e. net government transfers)
income share of GDP. A large number of countries have experienced a concomitant
decline in the labour share of GDP and in the share of capital income going to
households, suggesting that a rising share of profits has been retained by the corporate
sector instead of being redistributed to the household sector.
Yet, there are no clear links between the changes in income distribution between the
household, corporate and government sectors of the economy on the one hand, and the
rise in income inequality within the household sector experienced by many OECD
countries, on the other.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
13
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0017.png
Economic Policy Reforms 2016
Going for Growth Interim Report
© OECD 2016
Chapter 1
Overview of structural reforms
in the policy areas identified
as priorities for growth
This chapter reviews the main growth challenges faced by OECD and selected non-
OECD countries and takes stock of the progress made since 2015 in the adoption
and implementation of structural policy reforms to address these challenges.
Progress is assessed on the basis of actions taken in response to Going for Growth
policy recommendations. The chapter also discusses the potential effect of the
reforms on policy objectives other than GDP growth, in particular public finance
consolidation, narrowing current account imbalances and reducing income
inequality.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli
authorities. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights,
East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
15
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0018.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Overview of structural reforms in the policy areas identified as priorities
for growth
Main findings
The slowdown in the pace of reforms observed in 2013-14 has continued in 2015, even
after taking into account measures that are in the pipeline but that have yet to be fully
implemented.
On average across advanced economies, about 14% of the reform recommendations
found in
Going for Growth
have been fully implemented in 2015, while another 36% are
in the process of implementation.
For emerging economies, fewer recommendations have been fully implemented
in 2015 but initial steps have been made on around 44% of recommendations.
The share of implemented recommendations has generally been higher in Southern
European countries (in particular Italy and Spain) than in Northern European
countries.
Outside Europe, countries where a relatively high number of measures related to
Going
for Growth
recommendations have been taken include Japan among advanced
economies and China, India and Mexico in the case of emerging economies.
The intensity of reforms has also varied across policy areas. Relatively more actions have
been taken to lift the labour force participation of women, reduce the labour tax wedge
and to improve educational outcomes, while fewer actions were observed in the areas of
innovation policy, public sector efficiency or labour market regulation.
Against the background of weakening global economic prospects, there is a good case for
prioritising reforms that in addition to stimulate employment and productivity, can best
support activity in the short term.
Aside from higher investment in public infrastructure, these include reductions of
barriers to entry in services sectors with pent-up demand as well as reforms in the
area of housing policies and job-search assistance to facilitate geographic and job
mobility.
Countries with very limited budgetary room may have to prioritise on high short-term
returns or on low-cost measures and ensure that others are financed through means
that are as friendly as possible to employment and growth.
In countries where income inequality is a particular concern, the majority actions taken
on policy priorities are likely to help narrowing the income distribution.
Recent actions taken to boost growth are unlikely to help the countries with largest
current account deficits to narrow their large external imbalances.
16
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0019.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Introduction
Global growth is set to disappoint in the near term, with emerging-market economies
losing steam and the recovery in output and employment in advanced economies
remaining uneven. While labour market weaknesses are still a major challenge for many
countries, a key contributing factor across a majority of them has been the slowdown of
productivity growth, reflecting both weak investment in physical capital (machines and
equipment, physical infrastructure) and poor growth in multi-factor productivity. In most
advanced countries, the recovery in non-residential investment is lagging behind that of
GDP, substantially so among European countries (Figure 1.1). Lingering doubts about the
strength and sustainability of domestic demand, a difficult access to finance and subdued
growth prospects for the world economy are weighing down on investment (OECD, 2015a).
Figure 1.1.
Investment is lagging behind the recovery of GDP in most European countries
The difference between the 2014 and 2008 levels, as a percentage of the 2008 level
50
Gross domestic product
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
JPN
KOR
ISR
FIN
ITA
IRL
ISL
GBR
SVN
HUN
AUS
NLD
ESP
SVK
DNK
NOR
DEU
CHE
USA
SWE
GRC
MEX
CAN
CZE
FRA
POL
PRT
AUT
CHL
LUX
EST
BEL
NZL
-50
Private non-residential and government fixed capital formation¹
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
-50
1. The last available year is 2013 for Switzerland and Chile; 2012 for Mexico.
Source:
OECD,
Economic Outlook Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323716
While the weakness of investment coincided with the crisis, the slowdown in multi-
factor productivity among advanced countries goes all the way back to the early 2000s
(Figure 1.2), an indication that deep structural weaknesses may cast a shadow on future
growth prospects. The contributing factors deserving most attention include a slowdown
in the diffusion of innovation from firms at the technological frontier – mostly
multinationals which have enjoyed steady productivity growth – to lagging firms, weaker
investment in knowledge-based capital and a decline in the pace of business start-ups
(OECD, 2015b). Yet, in many OECD countries facing stagnant or falling working-age
population and declining returns to higher education, the role of innovation as a source of
productivity gains and medium-term rises in material living standards will become even
more prevalent. In addition, many countries are still facing high long-term unemployment
or relatively high rates of labour market withdrawals, in both cases contributing to skills
erosion, social exclusion and income inequality.
Against this background, the case for ambitious structural reforms, combined with
supportive demand policies, remains strong to lift potential growth. The 2015 issue of
Going
for Growth
identified priorities and formulated explicit recommendations to address the
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
17
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0020.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.2.
Labour productivity growth slowed even before the crisis in advanced economies
Average annual growth rate of GDP per hour worked,
1
percentage
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
ITA
GBR
SWE
FRA
1990-2000
2000-07
2007-14
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
DEU
JPN
CAN
USA
AUS
ESP
KOR
MEX
TUR
BRA
IDN
IND
CHN
-1
1. GDP per employee for non OECD countries. For Brazil, Indonesia and Mexico data refer to 1991-2000 instead of 1990-2000.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts and Productivity Databases
and
International Labour Organisation (ILO) Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323721
key challenges. In essence, recommendations have been made i) to develop skills and
knowledge-based capital, underpinned by the quality and inclusiveness of the education
system, ii) to improve policy settings in competition and innovation to facilitate the entry
of new firms and the smooth reallocation of capital and labour towards the most
productive firms and sectors, iii) to make growth more inclusive by removing obstacles to
higher employment and labour force participation of underrepresented groups such as
women, youth, low-skilled and older workers and by encouraging faster reallocation to
new jobs and ensuring that workers can up-grade skills.
This chapter reviews the main growth challenges faced by OECD countries and
selected non-OECD economies and takes stock of actions taken that relate to policy
recommendations on reform priorities laid out in the 2015 issue of
Going for Growth.
The
priorities are selected with a view to improving material living standards through
employment and productivity gains. The policy areas covered include product and labour
market regulations, tax and benefit systems, rules affecting foreign trade and investment,
education and training, as well as innovation. The chapter specifically evaluates the extent
to which the countries have addressed such reform priorities, mainly focusing on the
actions taken in 2015. The implementation of reforms is defined as the introduction of
relevant laws and decrees or appropriate measures (such as budgetary provisions) put in
place for the reform to come into effect. It does not, however, evaluate how effectively
those legislations or measures are enforced in practice.
The next section provides a global overview of the reform momentum in 2015
compared to previous periods. The subsequent section discusses the main challenges
faced by countries and reviews actions taken on policy recommendations to address these
challenges, with a special focus on developments that have taken place in 2015. The final
section discusses the possible impact of recommendations on other important policy
objectives, namely the reduction of income inequality as well as of budgetary deficits and
current account imbalances.
18
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0021.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
A global overview of the progress on reform priorities
On average across advanced economies, about 14% of the reform recommendations
found in the 2015 issue of
Going for Growth
have been fully implemented (that is, they were
met with relevant legislation or significant budgetary provision) in 2015, while 36% were in
the process of implementation (Figure 1.3 panel A). For emerging economies, although the
share of the
Going for Growth
recommendations that have been fully implemented
remained lower than in advanced economies, a higher proportion (44%) was in the process
of implementation (Panel B). Taken at face value, these numbers indicate a marked
slowdown in the pace of reforms in 2015 relative to the pace observed during the
period 2013-14 (Figure 1.4, “fully implemented actions”). However, considering that
legislative intensity can vary significantly from one year to the next, caution is needed in
comparing the pace reported in one year (2015) relative to the pace averaged over a two-
year period.
1
Still, even if one takes into account not only the policy measures fully
implemented but also the ones in the process of implementation – which may or may not
end up as fully implemented – the pace of reforms would remain below that of the past two
years (Figure 1.4, “full-implementation of in-process measures”).
Figure 1.3.
About 50 % of the
Going for Growth
recommendations have been implemented
or are in the process of implementation
Fully implemented (the adoption of relevant law etc.)
In process of implementation
Limited steps taken or no action
A. Advanced economies
B. Emerging economies
7.8%
14.2%
45.3%
49.4%
36.4%
46.9%
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323735
The actual pace of reform is more likely to lie somewhere between these two cases,
confirming the slowdown of the reform momentum observed since the peak of 2011-12.
The deceleration is most apparent in euro area economies, where it is now similar to the
pace observed elsewhere. Furthermore, the pace of reform in the euro area (current
account) surplus economies continues to be substantially below that of euro area deficits
economies.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
19
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0022.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.4.
The pace of reform has decelerated in 2015
The share of implemented
Going for Growth
recommendations
1
0.70
0.65
0.60
0.55
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
2011-12
2013-14
2015 (fully implemented)
2015 (full implementation of in-process measures)
Advanced
economies
Emerging market
economies
Euro area deficit
economies
Euro area surplus
economies
Non-Euro EU
economies
Non-EU advanced
economies
0.70
0.65
0.60
0.55
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
1. The chart illustrates the pace of reform in previous periods captured by the indicator of reform responsiveness (RRI) and the estimated
level of responsiveness in 2015 based on two different scenarios to ensure comparability with previous two-year periods. See the
Going
for Growth 2010
issue for an explanation on RRI, and the main text on how the hypothetical RRI is computed. Following Ollivaud and
Schwellnus (2013), the euro area surplus economies are defined as the euro area members for which the current account surplus was
on average larger than 1% of GDP over the period 2000-05 (Austria, Belgium, Germany, Finland, Luxembourg and the Netherlands). The
euro area deficit economies include the remaining members of the OECD euro area (France, Estonia, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal,
the Slovak Republic, Slovenia and Spain).
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323740
While in the aftermath of the crisis, the responsiveness to
Going for Growth
recommendations tended to be higher in countries that faced more difficult
macroeconomic conditions – in particular a very high unemployment rate (Figure 1.5) –
such relationship has been less apparent more recently: a high responsiveness has been
observed across countries facing diverse macroeconomic conditions.
Figure 1.5.
The pace of reforms has been faster in countries facing hardest
macroeconomic conditions
Reform Responsiveness Indicator averaged over 2011-14
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20 21 22 23 24 25
Unemployment rate in 2010
26
POL
GBR
ISR
HUN
FIN
CHN AUT AUS
CAN ITA
FRA
KOR
JPN BRA DNK
USA
RUS
NLD
DEU
TUR
NOR
CHL
LUX
SVN
CHE
SWE
BEL
CZE
ISL
0.0
MEX NZL
SVK
ZAF
PRT
IRL
EST
ESP
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
GRC
0.9
0.8
0.7
Source:
OECD,
Going for Growth
2013, 2015 and
Labour Force Statistics Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323752
20
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0023.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
There is also notable heterogeneity in the responsiveness to
Going for Growth
recommendations across the main policy areas. Among the reforms that boost employment,
the largest share of recommendations with actions implemented or in the process of
implementation is observed in the area of barriers to the labour force participation of
women, where action has focused on improving access to childcare services. On the other
hand, labour taxation, especially on low-wage earners, is the area where the share of fully
implemented recommendations is the highest. In the case of reforms that enhance labour
productivity, the area where most action has taken place is education, with an emphasis on
upgrading the contents of vocational training, improving teaching quality via revised
curriculum and new evaluation system, or increasing provision of early childhood education.
In contrast, relatively few actions have been taken in the areas of labour market regulation –
where more substantial actions had been seen during the past few years – as well as in the
area of innovation support and product market regulation (Figure 1.6).
Figure 1.6.
Reform intensity has been highest in the areas of education
and of full-time labour force participation of women
1
Share of implemented recommendations, percentage
Fully implemented (adoption of relevant law etc.)
Reforms enhancing labour
utilisation
Policy barriers to female labour participation
Tax system-Labour tax wedge
ALMP/Unemployment Benefits
Retirement/Disability system
Job protection legislation
Human capital
PMR, Trade and FDI
Tax system-structure and efficiency
Efficiency of public spending
R&D and innovation policy
0
10
In process of implementation
Limited steps taken or no action
Reforms enhancing labour
productivity
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
1. The chart summarises the share of recommendations made in
Going for Growth 2015
by the status of their implementation. Full
implementation refers to the adoption of relevant laws or equivalent measures.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323765
Yet, the weak global economic prospect calls for a stronger and more broadly-based
reform efforts across countries, not least to improve confidence and prop up investment. The
case is particularly compelling for reforms that in addition to stimulate employment and
productivity can best support demand in the short term. Aside from a shift in the
composition of public spending towards infrastructure investment, this includes reductions
of barriers to firm entry in services sectors with pent-up demand as well as reforms in the
areas of housing market policies and job-search assistance that can facilitate geographic and
job mobility, thereby easing frictions in the reallocation of resources.
A welcome initiative promoting concerted actions to step up the intensity of reforms
across major economies has been launched in November 2014 by G20 governments, which
have committed to raise their collective GDP by 2018 by an additional 2% through an
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
21
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0024.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
ambitious package of structural measures and macroeconomic policies (see Box 1.1). The
structural policies were assessed by the IMF and OECD as contributing more than 2% to G20
GDP by 2018 relative to the baseline if fully implemented. According to the joint
assessment by the International Monetary Fund, OECD and World Bank, G20 countries are
making progress towards implementing their commitments but more effort is needed for
the full and timely implementation that would be needed to meet the GDP objective.
Box 1.1.
G20 Growth strategy and its implementation
In November 2014, the leaders of G20 countries agreed to “ambitious but realistic”
policies with the aim to lift the G20’s collective GDP by at least 2% above the trajectory
implied by the existing policies over the coming five years. All G20 countries submitted
Growth Strategies (GS) that consist of macroeconomic policies to stimulate demand in the
near term and structural reforms to lift employment and productivity through stronger
competition, trade, as well as public and private investment. A wide range of reforms in
product and labour markets, investments in public infrastructure, tax reforms and
innovation policies were included in the GS.
This process brought a new level of ambition to global economic cooperation in this area.
It was based on a clear quantitative target and backed up by specific and detailed reform
commitments. While the process is member-led and based on peer review, it has been
supported by analysis from international organisations including the OECD. This included
an initial assessment of the policy priorities, based in part on
Going for Growth.
Many measures committed by G20 countries in their GS overlap with reform priorities
recommended in
Going for Growth.
Examples of such measures include regulatory reforms
to reduce administrative burdens to business activities, increase spending on active labour
market policies, vocational training and childcare service, and opening up service sectors
to foreign competition.
This process was also supported by a joint quantification exercise by the IMF and the
OECD that estimated the impact of the specific policy commitments. This estimated that
the full implementation of GS would raise the G20’s collective GDP by 2.1 per cent by 2018.
The OECD, together with the IMF and World Bank, is also supporting G20 countries to
track progress on the commitments and has provided a quantitative assessment of impact
of measures implemented before the 2015 G20 Summit in Antalya, Turkey.
Assessment of reform progress by country groups
This section reviews the main challenges and actions taken by countries on priorities
identified in
Going for Growth.
For this purpose, the review of actions taken is organised
around groups of countries sharing similar challenges and priorities (Box 1.2).
Group 1: Countries with extremely high long-term and youth unemployment (Greece,
Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Slovak Republic and Spain)
Those countries, particularly hard hit by the crisis, have seen a recovery in output
(with Greece being a notable exception) as a substantial reduction in unit labour costs
improved their competitiveness. However, their unemployment rate remains painfully
high, in particular the incidence of long-term and youth unemployment, which is the
22
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0025.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Box 1.2.
Country grouping by common challenges
For the purpose of this review, countries are grouped according to the common nature of
the most pressing challenges as identified in the 2015 issue of
Going for Growth
and
summarised here in the following set of tables. Challenges are examined at a level that
allows for groupings that are as meaningful as possible, though some degree of
arbitrariness remains inevitable. Many countries may be confronted with a similar
challenge such as, for instance, high and persistent unemployment. But beyond this broad
challenge, countries are also distinguished according to the more specific structural
factors and policy weaknesses perceived to be contributing the most to that particular
challenge. The country groups are shown in the table below.
With many countries sharing a great deal of challenges, there are some “borderline”
cases, i.e. countries that could legitimately belong to another group than the one assigned
in this exercise. For instance, Finland has been grouped with Austria, Belgium, France,
Luxembourg and Slovenia on the basis of challenges such as low labour force participation
of older workers and persistently high unemployment. However, it could also be seen as
belonging to a group comprising mainly of Nordic countries.
Similarly, a few countries only share part of the characteristics on their group. For
example, persistently high unemployment is not as big a concern in Austria as it is for
other countries in the group. In fact, one country – Iceland – could not be fitted in any
group and is not covered in the report. The European countries form four groups, while
the rest of the OECD and BRIICS account for another four groups. The EU as such is
not considered as a country and not covered in this report, although it is given
recommendations in the
Going for Growth.
For further details on the identification and selection of reform areas as well as underlying
empirical literature, see past issues of
Going for Growth.
Country Group
Group 1
Group 2
Group 3
Group 4
Group 5
Countries
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal,
Slovak Republic, Spain
Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary,
Israel, Poland, Latvia
Denmark, the Netherlands, Norway,
Sweden
Austria, Belgium, Finland, France,
Luxembourg, Slovenia
Australia, Canada, New Zealand,
Switzerland, United Kingdoms,
United States
Germany, Japan, Korea
Main challenges
Extremely high youth and long-term
unemployment
Large productivity gap vis-à-vis
advanced OECD countries
Strengths
Past labour market reforms improved
cost competitiveness
High cost competitiveness and strong
manufacturing base
Low average working hours and risks Highest productivity level among
in housing markets
the OECD countries
High unemployment and early exit
from labour market
Sluggish productivity growth
and low return to KBC investment
Low productivity in services sectors
and limited full-time labour
participation by women
Large productivity gap vis-à-vis
the advanced OECD countries
High productivity levels
Relatively flexible product and labour
markets
Good manufacturing export
performance and relatively low
unemployment
Large room for catch-up and strong
manufacturing base or abundant
natural resources
Group 6
Group 7
Chile, China, Mexico,
Russian Federation
Turkey, Brazil, Colombia, Indonesia,
India, South Africa
Group 8
High labour informality, infrastructure Large room for catch-up and high
shortages and low educational
population growth
attainments
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
23
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0026.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
highest among OECD countries (Figure 1.7). Such high long-term unemployment
undermines long-run growth through skills erosion and reduces the prospect of career
building and social mobility for affected youth, with the risk of a further widening of
income inequality (OECD, 2015c).
Figure 1.7.
Youth unemployment rate and the share of long-term unemployed remain very high
Percentage, 2014
1
80
Youth unemployment rate (15-24)
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
ESP
GRC
ITA
PRT
SVK
IRL
EU
POL
FRA
BEL
SWE
LUX
HUN
SVN
OECD
FIN
TUR
CHL
GBR
CZE
NZL
EST
CAN
USA
AUS
NLD
DNK
ISR
AUT
KOR
ISL
MEX
CHE
DEU
NOR
JPN
0
Long-term unemployment rate (% of total unemployed)
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Data for long-term unemployment for Korea refer to 2013.
Source:
OECD,
Labour Force Statistics Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323779
Addressing youth and long-term unemployment requires the mobilisation of a broad
range of policies…
The most pressing agenda for these countries is to mobilise a broad range of policies
to improve job opportunities for the unemployed and to facilitate their return to work.
Furthermore, reforms that raise productivity must be pursued to ensure mid- to long-term
recovery in output and employment. All countries in this group should extend and improve
the effectiveness of active labour market policies (ALMPs), in particular those related to
job-search assistance, training programmes and hiring subsidies. Resources allocated to
ALMPs in comparison to the caseloads are well below OECD average in those countries.
Recent policy actions in this area include:
As the part of the
Jobs Act,
Italy has established the Active Labour Market Policies Agency
(Agenzia
Nazionale per le Politiche Attive del Lavoro
or ANPAL) that coordinates ALMPs
implemented by local authorities and those by the authority of the Ministry of Labour.
Measures to ensure more effective monitoring and evaluation of ALMPs are also in
the pipeline.
Portugal launched in April 2015 the 43 million Euro programme “Reactivar” that seeks to
improve job prospects for the long-term unemployed over 30 years of age by financing
internships in the private sector during six months.
The Slovak Republic implemented subsidies to support the first jobs for youth under 29.
Furthermore, it is engaging in several reforms to enhance the effectiveness of ALMPs such
as establishing a first point contact in Public Employment Services that allows more
individualised job-search support or reallocation of labour officers in order to reduce the
caseload per officer by half.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
24
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0027.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Spain launched a new activation programme targeted at the long-term unemployed. It
also introduced a reform of vocational training programmes that focuses on the specific
needs of firms, while opening to competition the provision of training programs. The
quality control of activation measures were also strengthened.
Other important labour market reforms recommended to those countries would
enhance the effectiveness of ALMPs. They include expanding the coverage of
unemployment benefits to workers not covered (Greece, Italy and Portugal), narrowing the
gap in job protection between regular and non-regular workers (Italy and Spain) and
increasing the flexibility of wage formation by reducing further the administrative
extension of sectorial bargaining (Portugal and Spain). These countries have been quite
active in those areas in recent years: notably Spain and Portugal have been engaging in
reforms of employment protection and wage bargaining systems (OECD, 2014a and 2014b).
Most recently, Italy introduced a new employment contract with a less costly dismissal
procedure, along with the new social insurance for employment extending its coverage
while making benefits conditional on participation in active labour market programmes.
… together with reforms that increase educational attainment and employability
of youth.
Raising graduation rates from higher education – while ensuring that the skills
acquired better match labour market needs – will also improve youth employment
prospects and long-run productivity growth. Common priorities include raising the quality
of compulsory education and tertiary education by improving autonomy and
accountability of schools and universities. A particularly important related reform is to
increase the provision of vocational education and training (VET) with a better curriculum
and participation of employers and, beyond schooling, to improve access to job-related
training.
Recent policy actions in this area include:
In Spain, the reform of vocational training programmes mentioned above provides
life-long training opportunities for employed workers.
The Slovak Republic introduced a new funding system for secondary vocational schools
which allocates funds according to the performance of students in the labour market.
Reducing administrative burdens and entry barriers to specific sector would contribute
to job creation and competitiveness
Reducing the regulatory barriers to entry as well as the compliance costs associated
with complex regulations can stimulate business expansion and job creation. The
employment gains can be particularly rapid in industries with large pent-up demand and
low entry costs (such as some professional services) (See Chapter 2). Stronger competition
also fosters the reallocation of jobs from lower- to higher-productivity firms within sectors,
thereby improving the allocation of skills (OECD, 2015b; Adalet McGowan and
Andrews, 2015). The productivity gain expected from improving the matching between
workers’ skills and the skills level required for their job is particularly large in some of
these countries (Figure 1.8). Stronger product market competition would also facilitate
labour market reforms (Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2003). This allows for lower unit labour
costs which translate into lower prices, improving competitiveness as well as real wages in
these countries.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
25
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0028.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.1.
Reform priorities for countries with high long-term
and youth unemployment
GRE
R
1
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Make UB conditional on work availability and job-search
criteria/reinforce activation
Taper UB along duration/reduce age-bias in UB/reduce
progressively the combined generosity of UB and other
social benefits (i.e. reduce spikes in marginal effective
tax rates)
Expand the coverage or level of UB/social protection
and social services
Strengthen resources for job-search assistance
and training whilst improving targeting of ALMPs
Focus on well-targeted training programs/requalification
Strengthen monitoring and evaluation of PES
Job protection
Ease EPL on regular workers to narrow the gap with respect
to non-regular workers and tackle labour market duality
Minimum wages and wage bargaining systems
Reduce or eliminate administrative extension
of collective wage agreements
Human capital
Early childhood education
Expand access to quality childcare and early education/
improve targeting
Primary and secondary education
Improve curricula and evaluation
Other recommendations (reduce dropout, reduce
inequality in educational outcomes and opportunities)
Tertiary education
Increase university autonomy and accountability
or specialisation by institutions
Introduce/raise tuition fees flanked by income-contingent
loans/mean-tested grants, Improve targeting
of means-tested financial assistance
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships
and VET and their relevance to labour market needs
Expand access to and effectiveness of lifelong/job-related
education and training
Reduce economy-wide regulatory burdens
Reduce administrative burden on start-ups/complexity
of regulatory procedure
Reduce the scope of public ownership/state intervention
Ease business exit/bankruptcy procedures
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Retail trade and professional services
R&D and innovation
Increase public support/Improve targeting of public
support/evaluate grant programs
Increase and/or reform indirect R&D support –
tax incentives, seek balance between direct
and indirect support
Strengthen collaboration between research centres/
universities and industry
A
1
R
IRL
A
R
ITA
A
R
PRT
A
R
SVK
A
R
ESP
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
26
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0029.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Recent policy actions taken in this area include:
Ireland introduced the Legal Service Regulation Bill which would establish an
independent regulator for the legal profession.
Italy introduced relevant decrees aimed at improving the efficiency in the civil courts
and at streamlining bankruptcy procedures.
Spain is implementing the Market Unity Law that addresses internal market fragmentation
for product and service markets and simplifies business licencing and other administrative
burdens. It also took steps to liberalise passenger transport in railways.
Figure 1.8.
A significant share of workers face skill mismatch, implying
a large scope for productivity gains
Percentage of workers with skill mismatch and implied gain in productivity from reducing mismatch,
selected OECD countries,
1
2011-12
40
Percentage of workers with skill mismatch (left axis)
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Gains to labour productivity from reducing skill mismatch (right axis)
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
POL CAN BEL SWE USA FRA NLD DNK JPN FIN EST KOR GBR NOR SVK AUS DEU AUT IRL CZE ESP ITA
1. The figure shows the percentage of workers who are either over or under-skilled and the simulated gains to allocative efficiency from
reducing skill mismatch in each country to the best practice level of mismatch. The figures are based on OECD calculations using
OECD,
Survey of Adult Skills
(2012). Data for Greece and Portugal are missing.
Source:
M. Adalet McGowan and D. Andrews (2015), “Labour Market Mismatch and Labour Productivity: Evidence from PIAAC Data”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers
No. 1209.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323785
Group 2: Countries with a large labour productivity gap
vis-à-vis
OECD average
(Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Israel, Poland and Latvia)
Those countries have most recently enjoyed relatively strong growth led by household
consumption and exports. They also benefit from strong trade linkages with more
advanced European economies, in particular in the case of the Czech Republic, Slovak
Republic and Hungary, which are deeply integrated into their global value chains. Israel
boasts a competitive and innovation-intensive manufacturing sector. However, the gap in
labour productivity
vis-à-vis
the upper half of OECD countries remains large and with the
exception of Poland, convergence has been slow or even stalled since the crisis (Figure 1.9).
Weak productivity in the protected sectors accounts for much of productivity gap and slow
catch-up, especially in Israel (OECD, 2016).
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
27
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0030.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.9.
The productivity gap remains large with ample room for catch-up
Percentage difference in GDP per hour worked
vis-à-vis
the upper half of OECD countries
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts, Productivity and Economic Outlook Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323792
28
LUX
NOR
USA
BEL
NLD
FRA
DNK
IRL
DEU
CHE
SWE
AUT
AUS
FIN
ESP
ITA
CAN
GBR
ISL
SVN
JPN
NZL
SVK
ISR
GRC
CZE
PRT
KOR
HUN
TUR
EST
POL
LVA
CHL
MEX
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
-50
-60
-70
-80
2014
2008
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
-50
-60
-70
-80
While these countries are considerably more competitive than other European
countries in terms of labour costs, this advantage is expected to wane as their wage level is
likely to rise with their further economic development. In order to remain competitive,
they must therefore reinvigorate productivity growth via a wide range of reforms in
product and labour markets, investment in human capital and innovation.
Regulatory reforms to boost competition and entrepreneurship
In the product market, those countries are recommended to remove red tapes across
the board (Hungary and Israel), reduce the scope of public ownership (Czech Republic,
Poland and Latvia), and to lower entry barriers in network industries and professional
services (Czech Republic, Hungary, Israel, Poland and Latvia). Easing the strictness of
regulation in network industries (e.g. energy, telecommunications and transport) as well as
in retail and professional services would improve productivity and competitiveness in
downstream sectors, not least manufacturing, which use services from these upstream
industries as inputs for their own production (Bourles et al., 2010). This “knock-on” effect
of regulation in upstream industries on manufacturing through input-output linkages is
particularly strong in several of the countries of this group (Figure 1.10). Furthermore, such
product market reforms would put greater emphasis on new firm entry as a means to
strengthen competition, encouraging incumbents to increase innovation efforts to protect
their market shares.
Recent actions in this area include:
Poland introduced a law facilitating seaport customs clearance and compliance to tax
laws and information obligations, lowering thereby trade barriers. It also enacted laws
stipulating further reductions of entry barriers in professional services while improving
the legal framework for corporate restructuring.
Latvia introduced a law requiring specific measures to improve the governance of state-
owned enterprises.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0031.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.10.
Regulations in non-manufacturing sector have significant impact
on the manufacturing sector
The indicator of regulatory impact on manufacturing sector,
1
index scale from 0 to 1, 2013
JPN
ISR
FIN
CHE
ESP
KOR
CAN
NOR
SVN
DEU
SVK
NLD
HUN
MEX
ITA
IRL
GBR
GRC
LUX
DNK
EST
SWE
TUR
AUS
CZE
FRA
CHL
1. The figure compares the impact of regulation in upstream network industries (ETCR) as well as in retail and professional services, on
manufacturing sector. The impact indicator is computed using the 2013 definition of PMR indicator and domestic input-output
coefficients (except that of Korea which uses US input-output coefficient) and normalised across countries as an index that takes a
value between 0 (minimum value across observations) and 1 (maximum value). Data for Latvia are missing.
Source:
Égert and Wanner (2015), “The Regulatory Impact Indicator: the 2013 Vintage”, OECD
Economic Department Working Papers,
forthcoming.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323807
Higher investment in human capital and innovation capability
Ensuring a sufficient supply of skilled workers is essential for these countries to retain
and upgrade their comparative advantage in manufacturing. Raising the quality of tertiary
education and vocational education and training (VET) is of particular importance in
smooth school-to-work transition and skills development.
Recent policy actions in this area include:
The Czech Republic made an amendment to the Higher Education Act, aimed at
increasing the quality of higher education by reforming the accreditation of institution
and study programmes.
Estonia approved a law introducing quality standards and increasing the visibility of
adult training. A system for labour market monitoring and forecasting will be
operational in 2016. It also introduced a new grant system for university students which
offers flexible conditions and strengthened support to students of poor socio-economic
background.
In Hungary, the transition from secondary to upper-secondary vocational school has
been facilitated and the share of practice-oriented training in VET programmes has been
increased.
Poland implemented measures to engage employers to provide more workplace training
for secondary vocational education, such as an obligation for vocational university
programmes to contain at least a three-month apprenticeship or for companies
operating in special economic zones to collaborate with schools to develop their
educational programmes.
POL
AUT
PRT
NZL
BEL
0.14
0.13
0.12
0.11
0.10
0.09
0.08
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.14
0.13
0.12
0.11
0.10
0.09
0.08
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
29
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0032.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
With the notable exception of Israel, the intensity of business-based R&D in those
countries remains below the level in advanced OECD countries (Figure 1.11). An increase in
investment in innovation, especially in the ICT sector that often experiences high
productivity growth and acts as an input driving productivity growth in other sector, would
strengthen their competitiveness in the medium- to long-run. While a better targeting of
R&D support and a stronger university-industry linkage would enhance the effectiveness
of innovation system in those countries, significant actions have not yet been observed in
area of innovation policy.
Figure 1.11.
The intensity of business-based R&D is low compared to advanced OECD countries
Business based R&D as a percentage of GDP,
1
2013
3.5
ICT BERD
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
Rest of BERD
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
ISR
FIN
IRL
ITA
ISL
SVK
NOR
SWE
1. BERD refer to Business expenditure on R&D. Data refer to 2012 for Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany,
Hungary, Israel, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovenia, Spain Switzerland and the United Kingdom; 2011
for Australia, Austria, Belgium, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Mexico, New Zealand and the United States. The ICT sector is defined
according to the OECD ICT sector definition based on ISIC Rev.4. Data for Latvia are missing.
Source:
OECD (2015),
OECD Digital Economy Outlook
2015, OECD Publishing, Paris.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323813
Growth-friendly tax reform that reduces the labour tax wedge would enhance
employment
Those countries also share persistently high long-term unemployment that is partly
due to the high labour tax wedge discouraging the return to work. They are thus
recommended to reduce the burden of labour income taxation by relying more on less
distortive taxes such as VAT, environmental and immovable property taxation. Recent
policy actions in this area are:
Estonia raised the level of tax-free allowance and will allow low-income full-time
workers to apply for a tax rebate from 2017. At the same time, taxes on alcohol, fuel and
gas are to be raised.
Hungary approved a legislation that reduces its flat income tax rate from 16% to 15%
from 2016.
Poland reformed the fragmented tax and social security regimes across different labour
contracts by a law that makes all civil law contracts subject to the same social security
contributions up to the minimum wage.
30
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
GRC
GBR
CHN
HUN
KOR
MEX
ESP
SVN
CAN
TUR
NLD
CHE
DNK
DEU
USA
FRA
AUS
CZE
PRT
AUT
POL
BEL
EST
JPN
NZL
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0033.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.2.
Reform priorities for countries with a large labour productivity
gap
vis-a-vis
OECD average
CZE
R
1
Reduce economy-wide regulatory burdens
Reduce administrative burden on start-ups/complexity
of regulatory procedure
Strengthen the competition framework
Reduce the scope of public ownership/state intervention
Improve corporate governance of state-owned
enterprises
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Retail trade and professional services
Reduce barriers to FDI and international trade
Human capital
Early childhood education
Expand access to quality childcare and early
education/improve targeting
Primary and secondary education
Postpone early tracking
Other recommendations (Improve teaching quality,
reduce inequality in educational outcomes
and opportunities)
Tertiary education
Increase university autonomy and accountability
or specialisation by institutions
Introduce/raise tuition fees flanked by income-contingent
loans/mean-tested grants, Improve targeting
of means-tested financial assistance
Expand access/enrolment/reduce inequalities in access
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships
and VET and their relevance to labour market needs
Expand access to and effectiveness of lifelong/job-related
education and training
Provision and regulation of public infrastructure
Raise public and private investment in infrastructure
Enhance capacity/quality in transport, energy
or telecommunication/enhance connectivity
Introduce/increase/reform price signals/congestion
charges and user fees
R&D and innovation
Improve targeting of public support/evaluate
grant programs
Strengthen collaboration between research
centres/universities and industry
Tax system – labour tax wedges
Reduce average/marginal labour tax wedges
Reduce labour tax wedges for low-wage workers
(introduce/expand EITC)
Tax system -structure and efficiency
Shift the tax burden from personal income taxes toward
consumption, immovable property and the environment
A
1
R
EST
A
R
HUN
A
R
ISR
A
R
POL
A
R
LVA
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
31
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0034.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Group 3: Countries with low working hours and housing market distortions
(Denmark, the Netherlands, Norway and Sweden)
These countries enjoy the highest labour productivity among OECD countries and
also a relatively high employment rate thanks to strong labour force participation of
women. However, their average working hours remain substantially below the OECD
average and a relatively high share of working-age population are receiving disability
benefits compared to other OECD countries (Figure 1.12). These indicate further room to
improve labour resource utilisation. Therefore, the reform priority for these countries is to
reduce the policy disincentives to work longer hours and to remain in the labour force,
namely the high tax burden on labour and the generous sickness and disability benefit
system.
Figure 1.12.
The share of disability benefit recipients is among the highest in OECD countries
Percentage of population aged 20-64 years old receiving disability benefits
1
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
FIN
NOR
SVN
EST
HUN
NLD
GBR
DNK
SVK
USA
ESP
JPN
ISR
ISL
ITA
IRL
SWE
KOR
MEX
LUX
DEU
CAN
BEL
CHE
CZE
AUS
FRA
AUT
PRT
POL
NZL
0
2012
2000
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1. Disability benefits include benefits received from schemes to which beneficiaries have paid contributions (contributory), programmes
financed by general taxation (non-contributory) and work injury schemes. The last available year is 2014 for Estonia; 2013 for
Australia, Czech Republic, Finland and the United States; 2010 for Spain; 2009 for Mexico; 2008 for Austria, Japan and Korea; 2007 for
Canada and France; 2005 for Luxembourg. For 2000, data refer to 2004 for Poland; 2003 for Japan and Mexico; 2002 for the Netherlands;
2001 for Ireland.
Source:
Secretariat updates of figures published in OECD (2010),
Sickness, Disability and Work: Breaking the Barriers: A Synthesis of Findings
across OECD Countries,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323821
Making work pay more while preventing early withdrawal from labour market
Countries in this group are recommended to reduce the relatively high corporate and
labour income tax rates by shifting the tax burden to property and indirect taxation, such
as value-added tax (VAT), and also to remove tax expenditure on owner-occupied housing.
The high marginal tax wedge on labour income is hindering the work incentives of low-
income households and second-income earners in the Netherlands, while it is
discouraging above-average income earners to work longer hours in Sweden
(OECD, 2015d). As an example of recent actions in this area, Norway has increased the tax
value of secondary homes to 80% of market value and has streamlined tax expenditures
while reducing the income tax rates in a step-wise manner.
32
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0035.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Tightening access to sickness and disability schemes and re-orienting them towards
back-to-work and job-search objectives would help maintaining workers in the labour force.
Taking a step in this direction, Norway has reduced the generosity of disability benefit
calculation and is implementing a faster tapering rule for disability benefits and new
medical assessment for sickness benefits. Also, complementary reforms to curb alternative
channels to withdraw early from the labour market are needed, such as a tightening of
unemployment benefit entitlements. No action has been observed recently in this area.
Removing housing market rigidities to promote labour mobility and macroeconomic
stability
Another reform priority for those countries is to address housing market rigidities.
Stringent regulation on land planning and rent control as well as tax subsidies for owner-
occupied housing are depressing housing supply. This not only impedes efficient labour
mobility but also results in elevated housing prices, posing macroeconomic risks via higher
household debt level. The rise in housing price has been remarkably fast in some of these
countries contributing to an elevated household debt, especially in Denmark (Figure 1.13).
Recent actions in this area include:
The Netherlands reformed its rent control by increasing the extent to which the rent
reflects the property value.
Sweden has put forth a new housing plan that includes measures to streamline land-use
planning and incentives for municipalities to release land.
Figure 1.13.
House prices have risen fast amid large household debt
Percentage
160
Real house price, % change over 2000 Q1 and 2015 Q2¹ (left axis)
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
SWE NZL AUS CAN NOR GBR FRA CHE BEL ISR DNK KOR AUT FIN ESP USA IRL ITA CHL DEU NLD GRC JPN PRT
Percentage of gross disposable income
500
Household gross debt, 2014² (right axis)
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
1. The last available data refer to 2015 Q3 for Canada, Finland, the United Kingdom, Greece, Korea, Norway and the United States; For
Chile, data refer to 2002 Q1 and 2014 Q3.
2. The last available year is 2013 for Japan and Switzerland.
Source:
OECD,
Prices and Purchasing Power Parities
and
Economic Outlook Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323832
Better resource allocation and improved human capital would help further boost
productivity
In order to sustain their relatively high productivity level in the medium run, Nordic
countries need to reduce the scope of public ownership in network industries and entry
barriers in retails and professional services. They also have room to enhance the
performance of their education system by developing school evaluation frameworks, in
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
33
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0036.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
particular by improving teacher quality and strengthening vocational education and
training. Norway and Sweden have increased budget resources to raise teacher
qualification and salaries. The Netherlands and Sweden are recommended to reduce the
strictness of employment protection of regular workers, which would improve productivity
by enhancing the allocation of labour resource.
Table 1.3.
Reform priorities for countries with low working hours
and housing market distortions
DNK
R
1
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Make UB conditional on work availability and job-search criteria/
reinforce activation
Retirement and disability policies
Phase out early retirement pathways
(via disability or unemployment)
Review criteria to disability benefits, improve monitoring
and integration with ALMPs
Job protection
Ease EPL on regular workers (shorten judicial procedure, reduce
severance pay), narrow the gap with respect to non-regular
workers and tackle labour market duality
Ease conditions for justified individual or collective dismissals
Tax system – labour tax wedges
Reduce labour tax wedges
Tax system -structure and efficiency
Shift the tax burden from personal income taxes toward
consumption, immovable property and the environment
Broaden the tax base – reduce tax expenditures/subsidies
Housing/Planning/Zoning policies and regulations
Remove obstacles to the expansion of a private residential
market/reduce rent regulation
Improve targeting or reduce the use of housing subsidies/improve
targeting in the provision of social housing
Reduce/eliminate preferential tax treatment for housing
investment/reform property taxation
Loosen/reform land, zoning and planning restrictions
Reduce economy-wide regulatory burdens
Reduce the scope of public ownership/state intervention
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Retail trade and professional services
Human capital
Primary and secondary education
Improve teaching quality/improve incentives for talented teachers
(especially to work in difficult schools)
Improve incentives to secondary education completion/focus
on reduce dropout
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships
and VET and their relevance to labour market needs
Expand access to and effectiveness of lifelong/job-related
education and training
A
1
R
NLD
A
R
NOR
A
R
SWE
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, “A” stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
34
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0037.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Group 4: Countries with high structural unemployment and/or low participation
of older workers (Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Luxembourg and Slovenia)
The countries in this group are also enjoying levels of productivity that are among the
highest within OECD countries (Slovenia being an exception), but their unemployment
rates remain considerably above pre-crisis levels (except Austria), which along with low
labour force participation rates and low average working hours, contribute to low overall
labour resource utilisation (Figure 1.14). To a large extent, the low labour force participation
rate reflects the early exit of older workers from labour markets.
An important reform agenda for those countries is to boost employment by reducing
the institutional disincentives to labour embedded in the unemployment benefits and
pension systems. To ensure that reforms enhancing labour supply result in increased
employment, measures to remove impediments to job creation are also advocated, such as
lowering tax wedges for low-income earners and reducing entry barriers to industries with
strong potential growth.
Figure 1.14.
Shorter average hours worked and lower employment rates reduce
overall labour utilisation
Percentage difference in labour utilisation
1
vis-à-vis
the upper half of OECD countries, 2014
60
Hours worked
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
KOR
CHE
ISL
MEX
NZL
ISR
JPN
CHL
CAN
POL
EST
CZE
LUX
AUS
AUT
PRT
USA
OECD
HUN
SWE
GBR
GRC
IRL
SVK
FIN
NOR
NLD
DEU
DNK
SVN
EU
ITA
ESP
TUR
BEL
FRA
-40
Employment rate
Working age population
Total
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
1. Employment rate is measured as total number of employed divided by working-age population. Hours worked are measured as total
number of hours worked per employed. Working-age population is measured as working-age population divided by total population.
The total of the three components is not equal to labour resource utilisation since the decomposition is multiplicative.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts, Productivity, Employment Outlook
and
Economic Outlook Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323847
Institutional disincentives to job search and labour supply should be removed
In order to encourage more intensive job search, these countries are recommended to
reduce the generosity of unemployment benefits as the duration of the spell lengthens and
to activate job-search assistance and conditions at an earlier stage of the spell.
Furthermore, they also need to reduce labour tax wedges, which are among the highest in
OECD countries, and are particularly reducing job opportunities and incentives to take-up
work for low-income earners.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
35
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0038.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Recent policy actions include:
Austria in its latest tax reform has reduced the bottom statuary income tax rate.
Furthermore, earners with income below the first income bracket will be eligible for a
reimbursement of half of their social security contributions, up to EUR 400 per year.
Belgium has reduced the level of part-time unemployment benefits and tightened the
access to unemployment benefits for young people who have insufficient work
experience. It also introduced a revenue-neutral shift in the tax burden from labour
income to consumption and capital.
Finland has put in place a joint service involving central and local government bodies
that targets the long-term unemployed to improve the labour market skills and
employability.
In France, the earned-income tax credit providing incentives for workers to join the
labour force has been raised through the integration and a better targeting of two
existing measures.
Closing the pathway to early exit from labour markets
Encouraging older workers to remain in the labour market requires that a number of
measures be taken to raise financial incentives to pursuing activity, but also that the
working life evolves along with increases in life expectancy. The most essential reform is to
increase the statutory retirement age and to re-design contribution and disbursement of
pension so that it does not penalise continued work. Furthermore, these countries need to
tighten access to programmes such as unemployment insurance or disability benefits that
are often used as pathways to early retirement. On the other hand, provision of activation
measures such as job placement services and life-long training are also important to
support the attachment of older workers to labour market. Significant pension reforms
were put in place during the 2010-12 period, notably to help restore public finance
sustainability, but further action is needed to encourage the pursuit of activity at older age.
More recent policy actions in this area include:
In Belgium, pension age is gradually increased to 67 years by 2030 and incentives for
early retirement are being curbed.
Finland reoriented the wage subsidy system to those who are in the most difficult labour
market situations, namely to the long-term unemployed over 60 years old.
In France, an agreement reached by social partners will raise incentives for workers
covered by complementary pensions to remain in the labour force at older age.
Removing impediments to job creation will help to absorb more workers into employment
Reforms to increase labour supply may not increase employment in the short run,
especially during difficult macroeconomic conditions (See Chapter 2). To this end,
complementary reforms that boost hiring and job creation are needed, such as reducing
regulatory barriers to entry in industries with large scope for job creation.
In France, a recent reform (Loi
Macron)
eases somewhat entry regulation in legal services
and facilitates the creation of firms that can offer a wide range of legal and accounting
services in the same entity. It also expands the possibility for stores to open on Sundays,
especially in specific areas defined as touristic zones (albeit subject to agreements
between store management and unions) and introduces a partial liberalisation of long-
distance passenger coach services.
36
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0039.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.4.
Reform priorities for countries with high structural unemployment
and low participation of old workers
AUT
R
1
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Make UB conditional on work availability and job-search
criteria/reinforce activation
Taper UB along duration/reduce age-bias in UB/reduce
progressively the combined generosity of UB
and other social benefits (i.e. reduce spikes in marginal
effective tax rates)
Tax system – labour tax wedges
Reduce average/marginal labour tax wedges
Remove tax and benefit disincentives to low earners
full-time participation/introduce or expand EITC
Tax system -structure and efficiency
Shift the tax burden from personal income taxes toward
consumption, immovable property and the environment
Broaden the tax base – reduce tax expenditures
Retirement and disability policies
Phase out early retirement pathways (via disability
or unemployment)
Increase statutory or minimum retirement age
Lengthen contribution requirements to claim full
pension/make benefits actuarially neutral
Adjust benefits/retirement age in line with life expectancy
Job protection
Ease EPL on regular workers to narrow the gap
with respect to non-regular workers and tackle
labour market duality
Ease conditions for justified individual or collective
dismissals
Minimum wages and wage bargaining systems
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Retail trade and professional services
Human capital
Primary and secondary education
Improve teaching quality/improve incentives for talented
teachers (especially to work in difficult schools)
Other recommendations (reduce inequality in educational
outcomes and opportunities, etc.)
Tertiary education
Increase university autonomy and accountability
or specialisation by institutions
Introduce/raise tuition fees flanked by income-contingent
loans/mean-tested grants, improve targeting of means-
tested financial assistance
Other recommendations (reduce inequalities in access etc.)
Expand access to and effectiveness of lifelong/job-related
education and training
A
1
R
BEL
A
R
FIN
A
R
FRA
A
R
LUX
A
R
SVN
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
37
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0040.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Stronger equity in educational attainment and access to skills formation would
increase employability and productivity
While the education systems in those countries yield relatively high performance on
average, the individual scores are also strongly influenced by the pupil’s socio-economic
background (Figure 1.15). Education reforms that promote successful outcomes for all
students, in particular those allocating more resource to schools with larger
concentrations of students from disadvantaged background, would promote equality of
opportunities, social mobility and long-term growth. Similarly, better access to higher
education and skills formation opportunities such as VET and life-long training would
facilitate school-to-work transitions and enhance the employability of the low-skilled
workers. As an example of recent policy actions, France introduced a new individualised
guidance system designed for secondary-school students to prevent early drop out. It also
put in place priority education networks that allocate funding and teacher trainings across
schools based on the social characteristics of their students.
Figure 1.15.
Inequality in educational outcomes is relatively high
2012
PISA mean mathematic score
650
OECD average
600
KOR
550
500
450
400
350
0
2
4
6
OECD average
POL
NLD CHE
AUT
JPN
DEU NZL BEL
EST
IRL SVN
AUS
CAN
DNK
CZE
LVA
GBR
ITA
NOR ISL
LUX PRT
ESP
USA
SWE RUS
ISR
TUR
GRC
MEX
BRA
IDN
COL
FIN
550
500
FRA
HUN
CHL
400
350
SVK
450
CHN
600
650
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
Percentage of variation in performance explained by the PISA index of economic, social and cultural status
Source:
OECD (2013),
PISA 2012 Results: Excellence through Equity (Volume II): Giving Every Student the Chance to Succeed.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323852
Group 5: Countries with sluggish productivity growth despite relatively high
investment in knowledge-based capital (Australia, Canada, New Zealand,
Switzerland, United Kingdoms and United States)
Countries from this group have recently seen a slowdown in growth (except
New Zealand and the United Kingdom), as investment remained subdued, contrasting
with a comparatively good employment performance. Relatively low rates of youth and
long-term unemployment indicate that these countries have generally been successful at
keeping lower-skilled workers in the labour force. The flip side is persistently weak
productivity growth, in particular gains in multifactor productivity, despite comparatively
high investment in knowledge-based capital and a business environment generally
favourable to entrepreneurship, in addition to flexible labour markets.
At the same time, boosting productivity requires that a number of common structural
weaknesses be addressed, in particular in the areas of educational outcomes – to ensure
that educational qualification translates into skills – public spending efficiency, tax
revenue structure and public infrastructure.
38
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0041.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Ensuring further equity in access to high quality education would enhance
human capital
The performance of high-school students from these countries in PISA tests in science
and reading proficiency is only around the international average and with a tendency in some
cases (Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom) to show a high variation across
students. These countries need to reduce inequality in access to education at all levels.
Increasing the supply and quality of early childhood education and care (ECEC) is of particular
importance, as it influences the participation and performance of students at higher education
levels. In these countries, expenditure on early childhood education is relatively low, which in
some cases is reflected in enrolment rates (Figure 1.16). Reforms should be targeted to
minorities and less advantageous social groups, in order to raise equality of opportunities and
social mobility. Efforts are made by these countries to expand the supply of, and to raise
enrolment in ECEC. For example, the United Kingdom has committed to double the
entitlement to free childcare for working families with 3 and 4 year-old children from 2017.
Figure 1.16.
Expenditure on early childhood education is relatively low while enrolment
rates can be raised for some countries
1
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
Enrolment rates (%) at age 3 in early childhood and pre-primary education, 2013 (left axis)
Expenditure on early childhood educational institutions as a % of GDP, 2012 (right axis)²
2.4
2.0
1.6
1.2
0.8
0.4
0.0
1. Early childhood education target children aged below the age of entry into ISCED level 1. There are two categories of ISCED level 0
programmes: early childhood educational development (ISCED 01) and pre-primary education (ISCED 02). Data for Canada are missing.
2. Public and private expenditure. The last available year is 2013 for Indonesia. Public expenditure only for Switzerland and public
institutions only for Italy, Poland, Portugal and Switzerland. Data for Canada are missing.
Source:
OECD (2015),
Education at a Glance
2015:
OECD Indicators.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323869
ISR
FRA
BEL
GBR
DNK
NZL
ISL
ESP
NOR
ITA
SWE
DEU
EST
SVN
NLD
JPN
PRT
OECD
AUT
LUX
FIN
SVK
AUS
CZE
POL
CHL
IRL
MEX
USA
TUR
CHE
Most countries in this group have faced substantial increases in income inequality
during the past few decades. In some cases, there is evidence (the United States in particular)
that strong investment in ICT and complementary organisational changes have resulted in
faster replacement of workers by machines and software to perform specific tasks, while
increasing the demand for workers with complementary skills, favouring those with higher
skill levels (Brynjolfsson and McAfee, 2011). A wider access to higher education and effective
VET programmes can help mitigate the impact of skill-biased technological progress on
income inequality. As an example of recent actions in this area, the United States enacted
the Workforce Innovation and Opportunity Act which consolidates job training programmes
and aims to streamline services to assist job seekers. This reform involves concentrating
resources on programmes that have proved to be effective and become more responsive to
business needs.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
LVA
RUS
BRA
COL
IDN
39
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0042.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Growth-friendly and efficient tax system supports productivity growth
Tax reforms that shifts the burden from direct taxation such as income tax to indirect
taxation such as VAT, Goods and Service tax (GST) or property taxation contributes to
productivity growth by reducing distortion on labour supply and corporate investments
(Arnold et al., 2012). The tax revenue in these countries relies considerably more on income
taxation and social security contributions compared to other OECD countries (Figure 1.17).
They have room to expand the role of indirect taxation, for instance, by harmonising the
sales tax rate across regions (e.g. in Canada) or introducing environmental taxes. The
efficiency of taxation can be also enhanced by broadening tax base and scrapping ill-
targeted tax expenditures, such as the deduction of mortgage interest for owner-occupied
housing from income taxation (e.g. in the United States).
Recent actions in this area include:
Australia introduced in its 2015-16 Budget several measures to reduce corporate taxation,
notably a lower rate of corporate-income for small businesses and a more generous capital
write-off rule.
Canada introduced some measures to reduce direct taxation, such as increasing the
annual contribution limit for Tax-Free Savings Accounts (TFSAs) and a gradual lowering
of the small business tax rate from 11% currently to 9% by 1 January 2019.
Figure 1.17.
The share of direct taxes in total tax revenues is relatively higher
1
Structure of general government tax revenue, percentage, 2014
Direct taxes
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
NOR
Goods and services
Property
Other taxes
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
GBR
JPN
USA
CHE
DEU
NLD
SVK
ESP
SVN
KOR
HUN
TUR
LUX
ISR
SWE
GRC
MEX
AUT
DNK
CAN
CZE
FRA
AUS
PRT
POL
EST
FIN
BEL
ITA
NZL
1. Direct taxes refer to an aggregate of taxes on income, profits and capital gains, social security contributions and taxes on payroll and
workforce. The last available year is 2013 for Australia, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands and Poland.
Source:
OECD,
Revenue Statistics Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323873
Enhancing the effectiveness of public services and infrastructure
Providing effective public services in the face of mounting budgetary pressures while
containing tax increases is a challenge shared by many OECD countries, including those
from this group. An important reform priority is to enhance the cost efficiency of
healthcare while ensuring equity to access. Furthermore, in some countries such as
Australia and the United Kingdom, congested and depleted infrastructure calls for an
increased provision of infrastructure as well as regulatory reforms that enhance its
efficient use such as introduction of congestion fee.
40
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
CHL
IRL
ISL
0
0
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0043.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.5.
Reform priorities for countries with sluggish productivity growth
in spite of favourable institutional settings
AUS
R
1
Human capital
Early childhood education
Expand access to quality childcare and early education/
improve targeting
Primary and secondary education
Improve teaching quality/improve incentives for talented
teachers (especially to work in difficult schools)
Improve curricula and evaluation
Reduce inequality in educational outcomes
and opportunities
Tertiary education
Introduce/raise tuition fees flanked by income-contingent
loans/mean-tested grants, improve targeting
of means-tested financial assistance
Expand access/enrolment/reduce inequalities in access
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships
and VET and their relevance to labour market needs
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Strengthen resources for job-search assistance
and training while improving targeting of ALMPs
Tax system -structure and efficiency
Shift the tax burden from personal income taxes toward
consumption, immovable property and the environment
Shift the tax burden from corporate income taxes toward
consumption, immovable property and the environment
Broaden the tax base – reduce tax expenditures
Efficiency of public spending and services
Increase cost-efficiency in the healthcare sector
Reduce inequalities in access to public healthcare
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Reduce barriers to FDI and international trade
R&D and innovation
Increase and/or direct R&D support
Improve targeting of public support/evaluate
grant programs
Strengthen collaboration between research
centres/universities and industry
Provision and regulation of public infrastructure
Raise public and private investment in infrastructure,
promote private sector participation/concessions/PPPs
Introduce/increase/reform price signals/congestion
charges and user fees
A
1
R
CAN
A
R
NZL
A
R
CHE
A
R
GBR
A
R
USA
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
Some policy actions in these areas include:
The United States expanded the pilot project “Bundled Payments for Care Improvement
Initiative” conducted by Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services to over 2000
additional hospitals and medical establishments.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
41
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0044.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Australia is implementing its Infrastructure Growth Package which includes an initiative
encouraging State and Territory governments to privatise assets to finance new
investments.
The United Kingdom, in its Productivity Plan put forth in July 2015, prioritises the
upgrading of road network, to be achieved partly by spending GBP 15 billion on new roads
over the rest of this decade. It also sets as a target that superfast broadband be made
available to 95% of UK households and businesses by 2017.
Some reforms can increase the return to investment in knowledge-based capital
These countries are among those with relatively high rates of investment in
knowledge-based capital (KBC), a wide range of intangible assets that includes, beside R&D,
data, brand, design, firms-specific skills and quality managerial practices. While KBC is
observed to have contributed substantially to GDP growth in advanced OECD countries
(Corrado et al., 2012), KBC also generate knowledge spill-overs due to their non-exclusive
nature, thereby acting as an important source of productivity growth (OECD, 2013a).
Despite their high intensity in KBC investment, the subdued productivity growth suggests
that these countries are enjoying only limited return on their investment.
In order to strengthen the economy-wide impact of KBC investment, these countries
should encourage a stronger interaction between industries and research institutes, with a
view to improving the commercialisation of new technologies. Also, reducing entry barriers
and enhancing competition in industries (such as network and service industries) allows
innovative firms that leverage KBC to play a larger role as the driver of productivity growth
and the source of knowledge spill-overs. Similarly, reducing barriers to trade and FDI would
encourage foreign firms closer to the technological frontier to enter the domestic market,
facilitating the diffusion of new knowledge. However, limited policy actions have been
observed in those policy areas recently.
Group 6: Countries with relatively low productivity in non-manufacturing sectors,
fast population ageing and high barriers to female labour force participation
(Germany, Japan and Korea)
Countries in this group generally have a productivity level in services that is low
relative to the level in manufacturing, with the productivity gap being particularly large
compared to other countries (Figure 1.18). Lagging productivity in services is contributing
to economy-wide labour productivity being significantly below the average of the upper-
half of OECD countries (Germany being an exception) (Figure 1.19). Therefore, reducing
regulatory barriers to competition and innovation in network industries as well as
professional services and retail distribution remains a key common priority.
Another challenge shared by these countries is the rapid ageing of population. The
share of working-age population plus the older population under the age of 75 in those
countries will fall significantly faster than in other OECD countries (Figure 1.19). Given the
need to mitigate the impact of labour force shortages, boosting the full-time labour
participation of women has been high on the policy agenda of these countries. However,
this requires comprehensive reforms that not only remove institutional disincentives for
full-time labour participation but also that promote a working environment that can best
help to reconcile work and family responsibilities.
42
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0045.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.18.
The productivity in services sectors is low compared to manufacturing
Value-added per employee of business sector services,
1
manufacturing sector = 100, 2014
130
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
JPN
ISR
FIN
ESP
HUN
KOR
SVN
NOR
GBR
DNK
CHE
DEU
SVK
NLD
ITA
IRL
FRA
USA
CZE
SWE
AUS
POL
AUT
PRT
EST
BEL
0
130
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Business sector services cover distributive trade, repair, accommodation, food and transport services; information and
communication; financial and insurance; professional, scientific and support activities. Data refer to 2013 for Belgium, Denmark,
France, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Spain, Switzerland, the United States; 2012 for Australia and the
United Kingdom. The observation on business sector services in Japan is an estimate based on National Accounts for 2013 and
the 2014 JIP Database. The data on manufacturing sector for Israel include mining and quarrying while the data on business sector
services include real estate activity.
Source: OECD National Accounts Database,
Cabinet Office (Japan) 2013 National Accounts, Central Bureau of Statistics (Israel) “Product,
Productivity Compensation of Employed Persons and Capital Return 2005-13”.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323888
Figure 1.19.
A faster population ageing is expected compared to other OECD countries
Projection of the share of population aged 15-74 in total population, percentage
84
82
80
78
76
74
72
70
68
66
64
62
60
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
2025
2030
2035
2040
2045
2050
2055
2060
Germany
Japan
Korea
OECD
84
82
80
78
76
74
72
70
68
66
64
62
60
Source:
OECD,
Economic Outlook 96 Long-term Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323895
Strengthening competition in non-manufacturing sector boosts productivity in services
and the competitiveness of the manufacturing sector
Regulatory barriers to entry and competition have held back productivity growth in
non-manufacturing sector by discouraging innovation and impeding efficient resource
allocation. Such regulatory barriers have also undermined the competitiveness of
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
43
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0046.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
downstream industries, especially manufacturing, given that 30% or more of the total
value added in exports of manufactured goods is created with services as intermediate
inputs. This indicates that substantial efficiency gains could be achieved in services
industries by easing regulatory barriers to entry, which could in turn help boosting
competitiveness of the manufacturing sector. To this end, those countries are
recommended to facilitating entry and competition in network industries and other
services, namely in retail. In Germany, abolishing price regulations and reducing exclusive
rights in professional services is also a priority. Recent policy actions in this area include:
Japan passed a law ensuring the neutrality of the electricity transmission and
distribution sectors with regard to generation and retail through legal unbundling. It also
passed a law that facilitates the establishment of foreign enterprises and promotes
entrepreneurship in the National Strategic Special Zones.
Korea reviewed nearly 800 regulations and amended the laws underpinning 2 377
regulations under the Regulatory Reform
Shinmungo,
a system allowing citizens to
request reform directly to the government. It also launched the “Regulatory Reform for
Foreign Investment.”
Duality in social protection and training opportunity constrains productivity growth
Stringent employment protection on regular workers lowers labour productivity by
impeding a smooth reallocation of labour resource (Bassanini et al., 2009). Furthermore,
the significant gap in employment protection and training opportunities between regular
and non-regular workers has a negative impact on income equality and human capital in
those countries, due to the limited mobility from non-regular to regular contracts. These
countries thus need to reduce labour market duality by increasing the transparency in
dismissal procedure of regular workers while strengthening the job protection and training
opportunities of non-regular workers.
While there are few reforms in the area of dismissal procedure of regular workers,
some steps have been taken to strengthen the social protection of non-regular workers: For
instance, Japan is to expand Employees’ Pension Insurance and has extended the coverage
of health insurance to 250 thousand non-regular workers beginning from 2016. Germany is
considering a reform that limits the duration of employment on jobs filled by temporary
work agency workers to 18 months. Those workers are to receive the same remuneration
as comparable regular workers after 9 months.
Multi-dimensional efforts are needed to increase full-time labour participation of
women
Full-time labour participation of women in these countries remains limited for various
reasons: fiscal disincentives such as the joint taxation system or benefits and allowances
conditional on spouse’s non-employment; high costs, insufficient supply or ill-targeted
childcare services; lack of flexibility in working-time arrangement and long working hours
that prevent the take up of maternity leave. Duality between regular and non-regular
workers also discourages labour participation, given that women are overrepresented in
part-time workers (which are mostly non-regular contracts) in these countries
(OECD, 2015e). Therefore, reforms to boost women’s full-time participation should extend
to multiple dimensions covering tax/benefits system, public services and labour
regulations, whereas increasing the supply of childcare facilities or maternity leave alone
may not be sufficient.
44
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0047.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.6.
Reform priorities for countries with low productivity
in non-manufacturing sectors and high barriers to female labour participation
DEU
R
1
Reduce economy-wide regulatory burdens
Reduce administrative burden on start-ups/complexity of regulatory procedure
Other recommendations (strengthen the competition framework, reduce
the scope of public ownership)
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Retail trade and professional services
Reduce barriers to FDI and international trade
Reduce/reform public subsidies to agriculture
Job protection
Ease EPL on regular workers to narrow the gap with respect to non-regular
workers and tackle labour market duality
Ensure the enforcement of labour laws
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Expand the coverage of social protection and ALMPs to e.g. non-regular
workers
Expand/target job- placement schemes
Tax system – labour tax wedges
Remove tax and benefit disincentives to full-time female/second earners/lone
parents participation
Other recommendations (reduce labour tax wedge/disincentives to low income
earners’ full-time participation)
Tax system -structure and efficiency
Shift the tax burden from personal income taxes toward consumption,
immovable property and the environment
Shift the tax burden from corporate income taxes toward consumption,
immovable property and the environment
Broaden the tax base – reduce tax expenditures
Policy barriers to full-time female participation – other than taxes and benefits
Expand access to quality childcare and early education/improve targeting
Reform parental leave policies/work place arrangement
Human capital
Primary and secondary education (Ensure adequate school resources
and infrastructure, etc.)
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships and VET
and their relevance to labour market needs
Expand access to and effectiveness of lifelong/job-related education
and training
A
1
R
JPN
A
R
KOR
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
Recent policy actions include:
Germany boosted federal expenditure to expand the childcare services supply for
children aged 0-3 years and to raise the quality of childcare, in particular with regards to
facilities and equipment. It also abolished the cash-for-care subsidy.
Japan is increasing the number of childcare places in order to accommodate about
0.5 million children by March 2018. Also, after-school childcare centres are being created
to provide care for 0.3 million children by March 2020.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
45
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0048.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Korea introduced the provision of free childcare for up to 12 hours per day for all children
under five, regardless of the employment status of the mother and family income. Free
childcare will be prioritised toward families whose both parents work.
Group 7: Emerging-market economies with ample room for productivity catch-up
through investment in knowledge-based capital and better resource allocation
(Chile, Mexico, China and Russia)
Following several years (or decades in the case of China) of strong growth, these
emerging-market economies need to shift to new sources of growth to continue to catch up
with advanced economies. Productivity gains driven by resource reallocation away from
agriculture to manufacturing, capital deepening, integration into the global trade system
and the associated technology transfer have largely run their course. As the productivity
gap between those countries and advanced OECD countries remains large, those countries
need to step up investment in knowledge-based capital, improve resource allocation and
encourage a more widespread development of skills and human capital.
These economies benefited greatly from their high integration in global value chains
(GVCs) as suppliers of base materials (Chile and Russian Federation) or assemblers of final
products (China and Mexico) (Figure 1.20). However, except Russian Federation, their
manufacturing exports embody a relatively small share of domestic value-added arising
from services, where the value-added created by GVCs is often concentrated (OECD, 2013b).
To draw more value-added from their global engagement, these countries need to further
improve their capabilities in knowledge and skill-intensive activities within GVCs (such as
new product development, manufacturing of core components, or brand development).
Figure 1.20.
Strong participation into GVCs but considerable room
to move up the value chain
Index of GVC participation and the share of domestic service value-added
in manufacturing exports,
1
percentage, 2011
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
Backward participation in GVCs: Foreign VA embodied in exports, as % of total gross exports
Forward participation in GVCs: Domestic VA embodied in exports of foreign country, as % of total gross exports
Domestic services value added share of gross exports
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
SVK
CZE
KOR
HUN
SVN
FIN
POL
MEX
AUT
JPN
SWE
DEU
BEL
CHL
ISL
ITA
PRT
FRA
NOR
EST
CHE
ESP
TUR
ISR
CAN
GBR
IRL
USA
AUS
NLD
DNK
GRC
NZL
LUX
1. The index of GVC participation consists of Backward participation, which is the share of foreign value-added embodied in a country’s
exports, and Forward participation, which is a country’s value-added embodied in other countries’ exports, as the share of its exports.
Backward participation tends to be higher for small countries or those engaging heavily in assembly of final goods (ex: China, Mexico
and some central European countries). Forward participation tends to be higher for countries exporting natural resource and base
material (ex: Norway or Australia) and those participating in GVC as providers of core components (ex: the United States or Japan).
Source: OECD-WTO Trade in Value Added Database (TiVA),
October 2015.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323901
46
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
CHN
RUS
ZAF
IDN
LVA
IND
COL
BRA
0
0
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0049.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.7.
Reform priorities for countries with a large room
for productivity catch-up through investment in knowledge-based capital
and better resource allocation
CHL
R
1
R&D and innovation
Increase public support
Increase and/or reform indirect R&D support – tax incentives,
improve balance between direct and indirect support
Improve targeting of public support/evaluate grant programs
Strengthen collaboration between research centres/universities
and industry
Reduce economy-wide regulatory burdens
Reduce administrative burden on start-ups/complexity
of regulatory procedure
Strengthen the competition framework
Reduce the scope of public ownership/state intervention
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Reduce barriers to FDI and international trade
Legal infrastructure and the rule of law
Reinforce judiciary independence and accountability
Reduce the scope for public officials’ interference in decision-
making processes/corruption, increase business transparency
Financial markets regulation and supervision
Strike a better balance between liberalisation and regulation
in financial markets
Human capital
Early childhood education
Expand access to quality childcare and early education/improve
targeting
Primary and secondary education
Improve curricula and evaluation
Reduce inequality in educational outcomes and opportunities
Other recommendations (ensure adequate school resources
and infrastructure, etc.)
Tertiary education
Improve curricula and evaluation
Expand access/enrolment/reduce inequalities in access
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships
and VET and their relevance to labour market needs
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Expand the coverage or level of UB/social protection
and social services
A
1
R
MEX
A
R
CHN
A
R
RUS
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
Effective innovation policies stimulate business investment in knowledge-based capital
In order for innovation to play a larger role in economic growth, business-based
investment in KBC must be stimulated through effective support measures and a strong
innovation system including better networking between research institutions and firms to
facilitate the commercialisation of new technologies. These countries are recommended to
revamp or reallocate their R&D support and enhance university-industry or public-private
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
47
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0050.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
sector linkages. Increasing their stock of KBC conditions their ability to innovate and move
up the value chain, but also enhances their ability to absorb and assimilate the diffusion of
advanced technology from the global frontier.
As an example of recent actions in this area, Chile launched an agenda for productivity,
innovation and growth that includes the creation of a productivity commission, designed to
lay the ground work for more balanced and diversified development across sectors, and to
increase investment in R&D activities. Mexico launched the National Entrepreneur Fund to
foster productivity and innovation in small and medium sized enterprises.
Reforms that enhance resource allocation boost productivity and maximise
the economy-wide impact of KBC
Economy-wide productivity growth is shaped importantly by the extent to which more
productive firms can grow in size (Bartelsman et al., 2013). Also, reforms that strengthen an
economy’s ability to allocate resources to innovative firms magnify the impact of KBC
investment, for these firms can act as a larger source of knowledge spill-overs (OECD, 2015b).
By reducing further the scope of command and control regulations as well as the weight of
state ownership and entry barriers, these countries can better use market mechanisms that
reward competitive firms with larger market shares. Such reforms, together with those in
financial and labour markets to improve the allocation of skills and capital toward more
productive firms, would unleash productivity growth.
Recent policy actions in this area include:
Chile introduced a new competition bill that strengthens the sanctions for cartels,
introduces a more effective and transparent merger control regime and grants the
competition authority formal powers to perform market studies.
China lifted price controls on 24 commodities and services, including for some
categories of freight and passenger transport. It reduced the administrative burden by
abolishing or delegating to the sub-national level over 350 administrative approval
processes. Furthermore, with the removal of the ceiling on short-term deposits, interest
rates have been liberalised except for some policy rates.
Mexico is implementing the License and Production Sharing Contracts in energy sector
and has concluded three tenders. It is also opening up the insurance and telecom
industry to FDI. Furthermore, it launched a one-stop online shop for government
services and information that would reduce the administrative costs of start-ups.
A robust legal infrastructure is a foundation of economic growth, especially for
innovation-driven growth. A transparent and fair legal environment that ensures
protection of intellectual property and contract enforcement is crucial for investment in
KBC considering that new ideas can often be easily replicated, denying those who invested
in the development of such ideas the possibility to recoup their initial investment. Reforms
that combat corruption and enforce the rule of law would also stimulate entrepreneurship
by reducing the
de facto
entry barriers.
Recent policy actions in this area include:
China increased the transparency in business conduct by replacing the annual review of
enterprises by a requirement of annual disclosure of corporate reports to all enterprises.
Mexico passed its new anti-corruption framework and has accelerated the implementation
of a new justice system at state level.
48
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0051.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
The Russian Federation enacted the amendments to the anti-corruption law that
broadened the categories of public officials forbidden to have foreign bank accounts.
Also, Judges’ salaries are to be increased by 30% in 2016.
Reforms enhancing educational outcome and labour mobility complement KBC
in realising higher productivity growth
An intensive use of new technologies or other types of KBC increases the demand for
workers with skills that complements KBC in achieving higher productivity. A shortage of
such skills can be a bottleneck for countries in this group in translating investment in
innovation into significant productivity gains. On the other hand, new technologies will
inevitably displace workers with skills that are substituted by new technologies. This
underscores the importance of education reforms that enable more students and workers
with ample opportunities to acquire relevant skills. To this end, those countries ought to
further raise the quality of primary and secondary education and ensure equity in access.
They are also need to re-orient tertiary education to the skills demanded in labour markets
and to upgrade VET by improving teaching quality and curriculum.
Recent policy actions include:
Chile is processing bills to reform early childhood education, pre-primary education and
improve teacher pay conditions. The government has also introduced new legislation
that eliminates profits, tuition fees, and selective admission practices in primary and
secondary schools receiving state subsidies.
Mexico implemented the new national standard for primary and secondary teacher
performance, in spite of delay in some states. It also launched the Educational Infrastructure
Certificates, a new bond to finance the improvement of school infrastructure.
Reforms that remove barriers to labour mobility, such as granting equal access to
public services by migrant workers irrespective of their registration status, also boost
productivity growth by making it easierfor skilled workers to relocate to higher
productivity jobs in urban areas (OECD, 2015e). To this end, China should allow equal
access to education for the children of all migrants. Steps are taken as few cities have
issued residential permits to migrants.
Group 8: Emerging-market economies with high labour informality
and infrastructure bottlenecks (Turkey, Brazil, Colombia, India, Indonesia
and South Africa)
The last group consists of emerging-market economies in need of addressing a wide
range of structural bottlenecks in order to sustain strong medium-term growth. The most
binding bottlenecks include high labour informality and youth unemployment, severe
shortages in public infrastructure and low educational attainment.
Various institutional barriers to formal employment must be removed
Labour informality is often associated with poor employment conditions such as a
lack of protection against wage non-payment or hazardous work, lay-offs without notice or
compensation, and the absence of benefits such as pensions, sick pay and health
insurance. Informal employment, especially prevailing in India, Indonesia and Colombia
(Figure 1.21), and high youth unemployment (especially serious in South Africa) are rooted
on various rigidities affecting the formal labour markets: onerous labour regulation and
stringent employment protection (e.g. in India and Indonesia); high minimum wage and
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
49
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0052.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.21.
Informal employment represents a high share of total employment
Percentage of total employment, 2013
1
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
IND
IDN
COL
MEX
BRA
ZAF
CHN
TUR
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Data refer to 2009 for Indonesia; 2010 for South Africa and China; 2012 for India. For China, the figure is an official estimate for urban area.
Source:
International Labour Organisation (ILO).
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323918
non-wage hiring costs (e.g. in Colombia, Indonesia, Turkey and South Africa); and stringent
regulatory entry barriers and administrative burden that impede entrepreneurship and job
creation (e.g. in South Africa). In Turkey, the low statutory retirement age is discouraging
formal work at older ages.
The scope of reforms to reduce labour informality and unemployment in those
countries is wide, given the need to address both the high costs of formal employment and
weak job creation. Essential reforms include shifting worker protection from jobs to
workers by reducing the rigidities in severance procedures while introducing or expanding
the coverage of unemployment benefits; cutting social security contributions and other
non-tax compulsory employer payments; capping increases in minimum wages and
weakening administrative extension of collective bargaining; cutting red tape and the
administrative burden on business operations and strengthening active labour market
policies such as job placement services.
Recent policy actions in those areas include:
India amended its Apprentices Act, relaxing some rigid norms related to the hiring of
apprentices. Also, the firm size threshold below which companies can lay off employees
without prior government approval has been raised in some states. Furthermore, a
unified online portal for 16 central government labour laws was launched while making
labour inspection processes more transparent.
Turkey has granted permanent social security contribution cuts and wage subsidies for
the employment of young workers. The wages of workers receiving on-the-job
vocational training will be paid by the government for six months, and the employer
social security contributions for these workers will be fully subsidised for 3�½ years, if the
training ends up in hiring.
In order to reduce the barriers to entrepreneurship, South Africa lowered turnover taxes
for micro businesses and increased tax credits for the venture capital scheme.
50
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0053.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Addressing infrastructure bottlenecks through efficient regulatory settings
and better targeting
The large infrastructure gap that constrains productivity growth in these countries
should be addressed by crowding in private investments for instance, in the form of
private-public partnerships. Essential reforms in this area include resolving the
inefficiencies in regulation concerning tender, concession, land acquisition or project
approval as recommended to India and Indonesia. Also, a better prioritisation of
investment through an ex-ante cost-benefit evaluation (as recommended to Colombia)
would enhance the contribution of infrastructure investment to productivity growth.
Recent policy actions in this area include:
Brazil launched the second stage of the Logistics Investment Programme PLI, with
planned investments of BRL 70 billion through concessions by 2018.
Colombia expanded the incentives to coordinate better regional infrastructure projects,
namely prioritising larger regional projects in need. The plan also included general
guidelines for evaluating and prioritising PPPs with a methodology to be issued by the
National Planning Department.
As part of the “Make in India” initiative, India took measures that could encourage
private investment, such as relaxing FDI regulations in some sectors including railways,
construction, air transport services. It also introduced regulatory reforms in the energy
sector such as an enhanced transparency in coal allocation, a partial privatisation of
Coal India and the auctioning of oil and gas fields.
Raising educational attainment by allocating more resource and improving
teaching quality
As regards the performance of teenage students, the results from the PISA tests reveal
the poor international ranking of these countries, in particular in maths (Figure 1.15). This
undermines productivity growth but in some cases also contributes to high youth
unemployment (e.g. South Africa). There is considerable scope for increasing the resources
devoted to education (on a per student basis) and to improve the quality of teachers
through more comprehensive training and evaluation programmes. Furthermore,
vocational training must be revamped both in supply and quality in order to address the
low youth employability and skill shortage.
Recent policy actions include:
Columbia increased new fellowships for tertiary education and introduced a new system
of targeting student loans. It also foresees extending early childhood care to 1.1 million
infants as opposed to 400 thousand today.
Turkey adopted its Vocational and Technical Education Strategy and Action Plan 2014-18
which includes 24 specific goals to be monitored by performance indicators, including
revisions of curricula according to national professional standards.
Indonesia introduced a new syllabus while increasing the funding for education.
India launched the Skill India Initiative that includes expansion in quantity and scope of
skill training programmes and financial incentives for youth attending and completing
those programmes.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
51
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0054.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.8.
Reform priorities for countries with high labour informality
and infrastructure
TUR
R
1
Job protection
Ease EPL on regular workers (reduce severance payment)
to narrow the gap with respect to non-regular workers
and tackle labour market duality
Ease conditions for justified individual or collective dismissals
Minimum wages and wage bargaining systems
Reduce the minimum cost of labour/allow for age
or sector differentiation
Unemployment benefits/social protection and ALMPs
Expand the coverage or level of UB/social protection
and social services
Tax system – labour tax wedges
Reduce average/marginal labour tax wedges
Reduce labour tax wedges by reducing social security
contributions
Human capital
Primary and secondary education
Ensure adequate school resources and infrastructure
Improve teaching quality/improve incentives for talented
teachers (especially to work in difficult schools)
Improve school accountability and autonomy
Reduce inequality in educational outcomes and opportunities
Other recommendations (improve curricula and evaluation,
reduce dropout)
Tertiary education
Increase university autonomy and accountability
or specialisation by institutions
Improve targeting of means-tested financial assistance
Expand access to and effectiveness of apprenticeships
and VET and their relevance to labour market needs
Expand access to and effectiveness of lifelong/job-related
education and training
Reduce economy-wide regulatory burdens
Reduce administrative burden on start-ups/complexity
of regulatory procedure
Ease business exit/bankruptcy procedures
Other recommendations (Strengthen the competition
framework etc.)
Reduce sector-specific regulatory burdens
Network sectors (energy, transport, telecoms)
Reduce barriers to FDI and international trade
Provision and regulation of public infrastructure
Raise/improve targeting of public and private investment
in infrastructure
Promote private sector participation/concessions/PPPs
Financial markets regulation and supervision
Encourage private participation in financial markets/
gradually reduce state intervention while ensuring strong
prudential regulation
Reduce/reform public subsidies to agriculture and energy
A
1
R
BRA
A
R
COL
A
R
IND
A
R
IDN
A
R
ZAF
A
1. R stands for recommendation in that area, A stands for any actions that are implemented or in the process
of implementation.
52
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0055.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Cross-country policy issues with implications for international trade and FDI
Global trade growth has slowed and, compared to past trends, is particularly weak
relative to GDP growth, which may reflect a structural shift in the relationship between the
two aggregates (OECD, 2015f, Constantinescu et al., 2015). Yet, trade plays a fundamental
role in the diffusion of technology and access to high-quality imported intermediate goods
boosts productivity and competitiveness within GVCs (OECD, 2013b). Therefore, collective
efforts to remove structural impediments to international trade, such as non-tariff
barriers, are required to boost growth both in the short and in the longer term.
Some progress is observed at the global level, and to a lesser extent, at the regional and
country levels. At the global level, the negotiation on the Trade Facilitation Agreement
(TFA), which contains various provisions for improving the speed and efficiency of border
procedures, was concluded in December 2013, followed by the adoption of a Protocol of
Amendment in November 2014.The full implementation of the TFA is expected to reduce
worldwide trade costs by 12.5 to 17.5% (OECD, 2015g). Furthermore, some important
aspects of trade facilitation such as the availability of advanced rulings or streamlining of
border and custom procedures strengthen significantly countries’ integration into GVCs
via increased use of foreign inputs in exported goods or higher exports of intermediate
goods used as inputs in foreign exports (Moïsé and Sorescu, 2015).
2
Another breakthrough came in October 2015, when 12 Asia-Pacific countries reached
the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) agreement which covers nearly 40% of the world
economy. Aside from the reduction of tariff barriers, the TPP agreement includes
provisions that improve intellectual property protection, remove barriers to investment in
services, and increase consistency and transparency of regulatory regimes across partner
countries. While the immediate impact of the agreement on trade and FDI flows remains
uncertain given that many tariffs are abolished only gradually, the prospect of better access
to foreign markets may stimulate investment in the relatively short run. In the medium
term, stronger competition and increased inward and outward investment are likely to
stimulate innovation and productivity growth in previously shielded sectors, namely
services and parts of agriculture (Jorgensen et al., 2015).
At the regional level, the European Commission has taken a step toward the Digital
Single Market by adopting a strategy that lays out legislative process toward further
harmonisation in regulations and reduction of administrative burdens concerning cross-
border e-commerce and telecom markets. Another strategy related to the Energy Union
was also adopted, aiming for a fully integrated European energy market that involves
interconnections and a common regulatory framework. While tremendous efforts are
required to push through regulatory harmonisation in Europe, the return to such reforms
is large, involving substantial boost in trade and FDI across EU countries (Fournier
et al., 2015). The harmonisation in service sector is of particular importance, given that it
accounts for up to half of the value-added embodied in gross exports. The stringency of
regulatory barriers to service trade reduces not only imports but also exports of services,
for such restrictions are mainly behind the border and therefore weakens the
competitiveness of local firms as well (Nordås and Rouzet, 2015).
At the country level, some reforms in the highly protected agriculture sector and
energy subsidies have taken place. For instance, Japan has reformed its Agricultural Co-
operative system and relaxed some of the limits on corporate farm ownership, steps that
may promote competition and boost productivity. Norway raised production-level caps in
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
53
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0056.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
some agriculture support mechanisms so as to encourage a shift to larger-scale units.
Indonesia scrapped subsidies on gasoline and capped those on diesel – a welcome move
that contributes both to the efficiency of budget allocation and the environment. However,
the administrative price setting regime that replaced subsidies is cumbersome and still
inhibits the adjustment of domestic fuel prices to world prices. Furthermore, Indonesia
sharply increased import tariffs on food, clothes, cars and other consumer goods, which
pushes-up inflation and has a negative impact on household income.
Summing-up: a great variation in the implementation of reforms across
and within country groups
During 2015, the highest share of full implementation of structural reforms
corresponding to the recommendations made in
Going for Growth 2015
has been observed in
country group 1 consisting mostly of Southern European countries (Figure 1.22). Among the
countries in this group, Italy and Spain have been most active, while the intensive pace of
reforms observed in Greece in previous years basically came to a halt in 2015 in part due to
the political transition in the first half of the year. Despite a slower share of completed
reforms, other country groups could also end-up with a pace of reforms that is comparable
to the average observed across OECD countries over the past two years, if preliminary steps
in a number of areas are fully implemented. Within each country group, some countries have
been more active, for instance Norway (group 3), France (group 4) and Japan (group 6). In the
case of the two country groups comprising emerging-market economies (groups 7 and 8),
relatively few reforms have been fully implemented but initial action has been taken on a
substantial number of recommendations, in particular in China, India and Mexico.
Figure 1.22.
A large variance in the share of the
Going for Growth
recommendations
implemented or in process of implementation
1
Percentage
Limited steps taken or no action
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Group 1
Group 2
Group 3
In process of implementation
Fully implemented (adoption of relevant law etc.)
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
Group 4
Group 5
Group 6
Group 7
Group 8
0
1. The chart summarises the share of recommendations made in
Going for Growth 2015
by the status of their implementation at the end
of 2015. Full implementation refers to legislation of relevant laws or equivalent measures.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323929
54
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0057.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
The implications of growth-enhancing structural reforms for inclusive growth
and macroeconomic rebalancing
This section briefly discusses the potential impact of
Going for Growth
recommendations
and actions taken on policy objectives other than growth in GDP per capita agenda, more
specifically the narrowing of income distribution as well as of fiscal and current account
imbalances.
3
Many structural reforms yield double dividends in term of boosting growth
and reducing income inequality
The fact that in many countries growth in GDP per capita over the past three decades
has benefitted little low-income households points to the importance of structural reforms
that promote inclusive growth. The contribution of structural policies to trends in income
inequality has been well documented (see
inter alia
OECD, 2008, 2011, 2014c, 2015h), providing
many insights on how reforms could be tailored so as to yield the double dividend of higher
growth and reduced income inequality (see Chapter 2 of
Going for Growth 2015).
Many of the recommendations made in the 2015 issue of
Going for Growth
are expected
to reduce income inequality, especially those aimed at increasing employment (Table 1.9,
column 1). However, some reforms encouraging the labour participation of low income
earners and low-skilled workers can lead to higher wage dispersion at the lower end of the
distribution. Other reforms enhancing competition and innovation are often found to be
associated with wider earning gaps (OECD, 2011), partly through their role in stimulating
skilled-biased technology changes. This underscores the importance that such reforms be
complemented with measures to facilitate worker’s up-skilling and reduce skill mismatch,
such as better provisions of vocational trainings and lifelong learning programmes.
Across the ten OECD countries facing the highest degree of income inequality, the
number of reforms implemented or in the process of being implemented that are likely to
reduce inequality is twice as high as those that are more likely to increase them
(Figure 1.25).
4
The short-run budgetary pressures can be mitigated by a good design and packaging
of reforms
In many OECD countries, not least those with a very high level of government debt
relative to GDP, the need to pursue public finance consolidation remains high, especially
those where population ageing is likely to put additional budgetary pressures. Under a
stylised scenario of interest rates normalisation and a rising expenditure on healthcare,
long-term care and pension, government debt ratios are expected to rise in about two-third
of OECD countries even in the case where interest rates remain at par with GDP growth
rates from 2020 onward (OECD, 2015a). And the debt dynamic gets worse in the case where
interest rates exceed GDP growth (Figure 1.23).
Although
Going for Growth
recommendations generally contribute to fiscal
consolidation in the long run – in particular those that boost private-sector employment
(OECD, 2013c) – some of them are associated with non-negligible up-front increases in
public expenditure (or declines in revenues) and their implementation can thus pose
challenge to fiscal consolidation in the short run (Table 1.9, column 2). Countries with very
limited budgetary room may have to focus on low-cost measures or ensure that others are
financed through means that are as friendly as possible to employment and growth. The
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
55
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0058.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Table 1.9.
The implication of the
Going for Growth
recommendations
and actions taken on other objectives
Income
distribution
Labour market policies
Reducing the duality between regular and non-regular
workers (in job protection, training opportunity, etc.)/
reducing informal labour participation
Reforming minimum wage and wage bargaining
Extending the coverage of unemployment insurance
and social protection
Reducing the replacement rate and duration
of unemployment benefits/strengthening
conditionality on job-search
Improving effectiveness of ALMPs (job-search
assistance/individual follow-up/training
and re-skilling)
Reforming the tax-benefits system to encourage
labour force participation of the low-skilled
Reducing barriers to female labour force participation
(increasing provision of childcare, reducing fiscal
disincentives)
Reducing disincentive for continued work at old age
and tightening the eligibility to disability benefits
R&D and Innovation
Boosting innovation activities
(R&D and other investments in KBC)
Education/Human capital
Increasing the provision and quality of early,
primar and secondary education
AUS, BRA, CHE,
CHL,
CHN,
COL, CZE, DEU,
DNK,
FRA,
GBR, GRC, HUN, IRL, ISL,
IND, IDN, ISR,
ITA, JPN,
KOR,
MEX, NZL, NOR,
POL,PRT, SVK,
SWE,
TUR,
USA,
ZAF
AUT, BRA,
CAN,CHE,
CHL,
CHN, COL, CZE, DEU,
DNK,
ESP,EST,
FIN,
FRA,
GBR, GRC, HUN,
IND,
ITA, JPN, KOR,NZL,
POL,
PRT,
SVK,
SVN, SWE,
TUR, USA,
ZAF
AUT, BEL, BRA, CAN,
CHL, CHN,
CZE, DEU,
DNK,
ESP,
EST, FIN,
FRA,
GRC, HUN,
IND, IDN, IRL,
ISR, ITA, JPN, KOR,
LUX,
LVA, MEX,
NZL,
NOR,
POL,
PRT,
RUS, SVK, SVN, TUR, ZAF
CHE,
IDN, ISR, JPN,
KOR,
NOR,
TUR, USA
AUS,
AUT, BEL,
CAN, CHE,
COL, CZE, DNK, DEU,
EST,
FIN, FRA,
ITA, JPN,
KOR, LVA, POL, SWE
AUS, AUT,
BRA,
CAN, CHE, COL, DEU, DNK, EST,
FIN, FRA, GRC, ITA, JPN,
LVA,
NLD,
NOR,
SWE,
TUR, USA
AUS, BRA, COL,
EST,
GBR, IDN, IND,
LVA, MEX,
POL
-
-
-
AUS, CAN,
CHL,
COL,
CZE,
EST, IRL, LVA,
MEX,
NZL, PRT, RUS,
SVK,
SVN
+
~
+
-
~
+
CHL, DEU, ESP,
FRA, ITA, IND,
IDN, ISR,
JPN,
KOR,
LUX, NLD,
SWE,TUR
BEL,COL, ESP, IDN, PRT,SVN, TUR, ZAF
AUS, CHL,
CHN, GRC, IDN,
ITA, JPN,
KOR, PRT,
RUS,TUR
BEL,
FIN, FRA, IRL, LUX, NLD, PRT, SVN
Budget
balance
Current
account
position
Countries with priorities in this area
(countries
taking related action in bold)
~
+
+
-/~
ESP, EST, FRA,
GRC,
GBR,
IRL,
ISR, ITA,
LVA,
NLD, PRT,RUS, SVK, USA,
ZAF
AUT, BEL,
COL, CZE, DEU,
EST,
FIN,
FRA, GBR,
HUN,
IRL,
ISR, ITA,
LUX, LVA,
NLD,
POL, SVN,
SWE,
TUR
-
AUS,
CHE,
CHL,
COL,
CZE, DEU, GBR, IRL, JPN,
KOR,
NLD, NZL,
POL,SVK,
TUR, USA
AUT, BEL,
DNK, EST,
FIN,
HUN,
LUX,
NLD,
NOR,POL,
SVN, SWE, TUR,
USA
+/~
-/~
+
-/~
~
+
-
+
-
Increasing the outcome of tertiary education/broadening
access to VET and life-long training
Product Market Reform
Reforming product market regulation (PMR)
to enhance competition, trade and FDI
Reducing agricultural and energy subsidy
Tax reform
Shifting the burden from direct to indirect taxation
(including fiscal devaluations, etc.)
Enhancing the efficiency of tax system
(cutting back tax expenditure, broadening tax base,
fighting tax evasion)
Infrastructure
Increasing investment in public infrastructure
+
-/~
-
-/~
+
+
~
-/~
~
+
+/~
+
+
-
-
Note:
The table summarises the expected short- to medium-run impact of each type of reform in attaining the policy
objectives. “+” corresponds to the case where the reform is likely to contribute to the objective whereas “-
”corresponds to the case where it is unlikely to help or generate a short-run trade-off. “~” corresponds to the case
where the impact is ambiguous due to opposing effects. Blank corresponds to the case of no direct effects. The
country code in bold corresponds to the case where policy action is taken.
56
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0059.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
short-run impacts on fiscal expenditure can be also mitigated by implementing in tandem
reforms that enable fiscal savings. An example of such “packaging” is a strengthening of
conditionality of unemployment benefits on activation measures while expanding ALMPs,
as is being done in Italy. Furthermore, some reforms can be implemented in a cost-efficient
manner through adequate regulatory reforms. For instance, enabling competition and
adequate pricing in network sector can stimulate private investment in public
infrastructure.
Figure 1.23.
Government debt levels will likely rise in a majority of OECD countries
with normalisation of interest rates and population ageing
Debt level in 2014 and simulated debt levels in 2030,
1
as a percentage of GDP
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
Debt level in 2014
Debt level in 2030 when the interest rate equals the GDP growth rate
Debt level in 2030 when the interest rate exceeds the GDP growth rate
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
SVN
NLD
GBR
SVK
FIN
DEU
CAN
HUN
USA
ESP
ISR
BEL
KOR
AUS
CHE
SWE
CZE
DNK
AUT
FRA
LUX
EST
1. The chart compares the government debt level in 2014 and the simulated level in 2030 under two alternative scenarios on the
evolution of the interest rate and the GDP growth rate. See the source for the details of assumptions made in the simulation.
Source:
OECD (2015),
OECD Economic Outlook,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323931
Among the ten OECD countries with the largest primary deficits and the highest
government debt levels, the majority of reforms implemented or in the process of
implementation are likely to put short-term pressures on the budgetary balance
(Figure 1.25).
5
Reforms can help rebalancing the structural component of current account deficits
or surplus
While current account imbalances declined substantially after the crisis, about one
half of the decline is explained by cyclical factors, namely large contractions in domestic
demand on the back of bursting housing bubbles in a number of deficit countries (Ollivaud
and Schwellnus, 2013). The narrowing of cyclically-adjusted global current account
imbalances reflects a substantial narrowing for all major trading areas except the euro
area, where the cyclically-adjusted balance of surplus countries continued to widen while
that of deficit countries narrowed by about one percentage point (Figure 1.24).This
underscores the importance of removing the institutional distortions that alter
households’ saving behaviour or return to private investment. For deficit countries,
reforms in labour and product markets that reduce labour or business costs may also help
to reduce imbalances by improving competitiveness.
EA15
PRT
POL
JPN
NZL
ITA
ISL
IRL
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
57
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0060.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
Figure 1.24.
The non-cyclical component of external imbalances remain substantial
Business and housing-cycle adjusted components of current account balances, as a percentage of GDP
1
Non-cyclical component
Business and housing cycle component
Headline current account
A. United States
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
-6
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
-7
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
2000
2001
2002
2003
B. Euro deficit countries
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2012
2012
2013
2013
2013
C. Japan
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
2000
2001
2002
D. Euro surplus countries
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
E. China
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
F. Oil zone
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
1. The chart decomposes the headline current account imbalances to the component explained by business and housing cycle and the
non-cyclical component. Following Ollivaud and Schwellnus (2013), the euro area surplus countries are defined to include euro area
members for which the current account surplus was on average larger than 1% of GDP over the period 2000-05 (Austria, Belgium,
Germany, Finland, Luxembourg and the Netherlands). The euro area deficit zone includes the remaining members of the OECD euro
area (France, Estonia, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia and Spain).
Source:
Updated calculations based on P. Ollivaud and C. Schwellnus (2013), "The Post-crisis Narrowing of International Imbalances:
Cyclical or Durable?” OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 1062, OECD Publishing, Paris.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323943
58
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
2014
2014
2014
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0061.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
The expected contribution of structural reforms to a stronger current account
summarised in the third column of Table 1.9 suggests that reducing the minimum costs of
labour by reforming worker’s bargaining power help deficit countries to rebalance the non-
cyclical component of imbalances. Similarly, cutting back subsidies or tax incentives that
lead to excessive consumption or investment in specific products may also help. For
countries with a large current account surplus, regulatory reforms and fiscal supports that
boost investment in physical and knowledge-based capital as well as higher investment in
public infrastructure can contribute to reducing the structural component of the current
account. Furthermore, promoting the full-time labour force participation of women and
older workers may also work towards rebalancing by increasing income of those groups
and thereby reducing the need for precautionary or retirement saving.
Figure 1.25.
The actions taken are likely to help reduce inequality
but not macroeconomic imbalances
Number of
Going for Growth
recommendations implemented or in process of implementation
1
20
Reforms that contribute to objectives
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
Reducing income inequality
Fiscal consolidation
Current account rebalancing
Reforms that do not contribute
20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1. The chart summarises the number of recommendations implemented or in the process of implementation by the group of countries
facing highest income inequality, fiscal and external imbalances. See footnotes in the text for the methodology for selecting those
countries.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323951
Across countries facing largest external imbalances, there are similar numbers of
reforms that have been implemented or are in process of implementation that are likely or
unlikely to help reducing those imbalances in the short run (Figure 1.25).
6
However, while
the reforms undertaken by countries with largest external surpluses are overall likely to
help the rebalancing, none of those undertaken by countries with largest deficits are
expected to contribute to the narrowing of imbalances.
Notes
1. This may be particularly the case when the indicator is compiled and averaged over a relatively
small group of countries such as the group of emerging-market economies.
2. The TFA will enter into force once two-thirds of members have completed their domestic
ratification process of the Protocol. Some of the largest trading countries such as the United States,
European Union and its member states, China and Japan have completed the ratification process.
3. The implication on the environment are not covered in this chapter, given that there are only very
few reforms that directly affects environment and that such impacts are importantly shaped by
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
59
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0062.png
1. OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
the environmental regulations in place (see Chapter 3 of the 2015 issue of
Going for Growth
for an
in-depth discussion).
4. The 10 OECD countries with highest income inequality are chosen on a basis of an index that
combines the standardised values of Gini coefficients and relative poverty rate. They are: Mexico,
Chile, Turkey, the United States, Israel, Japan, Greece, Spain, Australia and Portugal.
5. The 10 OECD countries with the largest fiscal imbalance are chosen on basis of an index that
combines the standardised value of cyclically-adjusted primary balance deficits (percentage of
potential GDP) and of government debt (percentage of GDP). They are: Japan, the United Kingdom,
the United States, France, Canada, Ireland, Belgium, Slovenia, Spain and the Netherlands.
6. The group of countries with the largest external imbalances are the 10 countries selected on the
basis of an index that combines the standardised value of current account deficits (averaged over
2010-14) and external debt (both as percentage of GDP) and the 10 countries with the largest
current account surplus. The largest deficit countries are: Greece, Turkey, Portugal, Poland,
New Zealand, Australia, Spain, Latvia, Colombia and the Slovak Republic, while the largest surplus
countries are: Norway, Switzerland, the Netherlands, Sweden, Germany, Denmark, Luxembourg,
Korea, Russian Federation and Slovenia.
Bibliography
Adalet McGowan, M. and D. Andrews (2015), “Labour Market Mismatch and Labour Productivity:
Evidence from PIAAC Data”
OECD Economics Department Working Paper
No. 1209.
Arnold, J. et al. (2011), “Tax Policy for Economic Recovery and Growth”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 121,
59-80.
Bartelsman, E. et al. (2013), “Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and
Selection”, American Economic Review 2013, 103(1): 305-334.
Bassanini, A. et al. (2009), “Job Protection Legislation and Productivity Growth in OECD Countries”,
Economic Policy, April 2009 pp. 349-402.
Blanchard, O. and F. Giavazzi (2003), “Macroeconomic Effects of Regulation and Deregulation in Goods
and Labour Markets”,
The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 118(3), pp. 879-907.
Brynjolfsson, E., and A. McAfee. (2011), Race Against the Machine. Lexington: Digital Frontier Press.
Constantinescu, C., A. Mattoo, and M. Ruta (2015), “The Global Trade Slowdown: Cyclical or
Structural?”
IMF Working Paper
WP15/6.
Corrado, C., J. Haskel, C. Jona-Lasinio and M. Iommi (2012), “Intangible Capital and Growth in Advanced
Economies: Measurement Methods and Comparative Results”, INTAN-Invest Mimeo.
Fournier, J. et al. (2015), “Implicit Regulatory Barriers in the EU Single Market: New Empirical Evidence
from Gravity Models”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 1181, OECD Publishing.
http:/
/dx.doi.org/10.1787/5js7xj0xckf6-en.
Jorgenson, D.W., K. Nomura and J.D. Samuels (2015), “Trade Agreements and Trans-Pacific
Competition” EU-VOX Column, 8 July 2015.
Moïsé, E. and S. Sorescu (2015), “Contribution of Trade Facilitation Measures to the Operation of Supply
Chains”, OECD
Trade Policy Papers,
No. 181, OECD Publishing, Paris.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
5js0bslh9m25-en.
Nordås, H. K. and D. Rouzet (2015), “The Impact of Services Trade Restrictiveness on Trade Flows: First
Estimates”,
OECD Trade Policy Papers,
No. 178, OECD Publishing Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
5js6ds9b6kjb-en.
OECD (2008), Growing Unequal? Income Distribution and Poverty in OECD Countries, OECD Publishing,
Paris.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264044197-en.
OECD (2011), Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/
10.1787/9789264119536-en.
OECD (2013a), Supporting Investment in Knowledge Capital, Growth and Innovation, OECD Publishing,
Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264193307-en.
OECD (2013b), Interconnected Economies: Benefiting from Global Value Chains, OECD Publishing,
Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264189560-en.
60
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0063.png
1.
OVERVIEW OF STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN THE POLICY AREAS IDENTIFIED AS PRIORITIES FOR GROWTH
OECD (2013c), Economic Policy Reforms 2013: Going for Growth, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://
dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2013-en.
OECD (2014a), The 2012 Labour Market Reform in Spain: A Preliminary Assessment, OECD Publishing,
Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264213586-en.
OECD (2014b), OECD
Economic Surveys: Portugal 2014,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
eco_surveys-prt-2014-en.
OECD (2014c), All on Board – Making Inclusive Growth Happen, OECD Publishing, Paris,
www.oecd.org/
inclusive-growth/All-on-Board-Making-Inclusive-GrowthHappen.pdf.
OECD (2015a), OECD Economic Outlook June 2015, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
eco_outlook-v2015-1-en.
OECD (2015b), The Future of Productivity, OECD Publishing, Paris. Accessible from:
www.oecd.org/
economy/the-future-of-productivity.htm.
OECD (2015c), 2015
Employment Outlook,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/empl_outlook-
2015-en.
OECD (2015d), 2015
Going for Growth,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2015-en.
OECD (2015e), OECD
Economic Surveys: China 2015,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
growth-2015-en.
OECD (2015f),
OECD Economic Outlook November 2015,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
eco_outlook-v2015-2-en.
OECD (2015g), “Implementation of the WTO Trade Facilitation Agreement: The Potential Impact on
Trade Costs” available from
www.oecd.org/trade/tradedev/WTO-TF-Implementation-Policy-
Brief_EN_2015_06.pdf.
OECD (2015h), In It Together: Why Less Inequality Benefits All, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/
10.1787/9789264235120-en.
OECD (2016), OECD
Economic Surveys: Israel 2016,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
eco_surveys-isr-2016-en.
Ollivaud, P. and C. Schwellnus (2013), “The Post-crisis Narrowing of International Imbalances: Cyclical
or Durable?”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 1062, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://
dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k44t7j9sdtc-en.
Sakellaris, P. and D.J. Wilson (2004), “Quantifying Embodied Technological Change” Review of
Economic Dynamics 7 (2004) 1-26.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
61
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0065.png
Economic Policy Reforms 2016
Going for Growth Interim Report
© OECD 2016
Chapter 2
Reform priorities
in a difficult macro context
This chapter reviews the main issues related to the short-term impact of structural
reforms in different macroeconomic contexts and takes stock of existing theoretical
and empirical studies. Taking reforms introduced in “normal” times as a
benchmark, it reviews the available evidence on the impact of reforms that are
implemented in “bad” times – i.e. in the presence of a sizeable negative output gap
and persistently weak demand – as well as under different assumptions regarding
the availability or effectiveness of macroeconomic policies in supporting the reforms.
In doing so the chapter focuses on the key channels through which different reforms
influence short-term activity via the main components of demand and discusses
how these channels operate under different macro conditions.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities.
The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem
and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
63
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0066.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Reform priorities in a difficult macro context
Main Findings
In a context of weak demand, structural reform strategies should put more weight on
measures that in addition to stimulating medium-term employment and productivity
can best support demand in the short term. The reforms most likely to achieve this
include:
Shift in the composition of public spending towards investment:
More specifically, public
infrastructure investment that effectively increases the growth potential in the
medium term (e.g. high-speed broadband network) can stimulate private investment
in the short term.
Product market reforms in specific service sectors:
Reforming rules restricting the entry of
new suppliers (exclusive rights) and the capacity of existing suppliers to compete (fees
control) in services characterised by relatively low entry costs (e.g. professional services,
taxis, etc.) can yield positive short-term gains in employment and domestic demand.
Reforms of benefit entitlements in the areas of pension or health:
Reforming pension or
health systems to contain future ageing-related costs can create the space for short-
term stimulus measures and raise their effectiveness, notably through increased
confidence in the sustainability of public finances. The gains from such reforms can
exceed the cost in the short term to the extent that only future benefits are reduced.
Reforms easing frictions in the reallocation of resources:
Reducing barriers to geographic or
jobs mobility can increase the speed of employment gains in difficult times. Housing
market policies that promote residential mobility include the lowering of transaction
taxes or costs on buying properties as well as the reduction of the stringency of rental
regulation.
In contrast, the risks that reforms fail to lift activity in the short run – or that they even
further depress demand – are highest in the case of reforms that initially put downward
pressures on wages or mark-ups, such as reforms of employment protection legislation,
minimum wages or product market regulation in network industries. A number of
measures could help mitigate those risks:
Reform packaging:
Simultaneous reforms of labour and product markets may reduce
the risk or extent of contractionary effects. First, the price reduction resulting from
product market reforms will ease the downward pressure on the real wage from labour
market reforms. Second, labour market reforms will facilitate the necessary
reallocation of workers arising from product market reforms as rents are redistributed
across firms and sectors.
Reform synchronisation:
In the case of the euro area, a greater synchronisation of
reforms will also help reduce the transition costs by giving greater scope to monetary
policy to mitigate the potential rise in real interest rates.
64
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0067.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Increasing the short-term payoff from structural reforms also calls for measures that
shift the relative strength of the transmission channels from supply-side reforms to
demand components.
Addressing financial sector dysfunctions to improve the credit flow:
Significant progress has
been achieved in cleaning the banking sector balance sheet following the crisis.
However, the share of non-performing loans in the banking system remains relatively
high in a number of euro area countries. In fact, the relative speed at which banks’
balance sheets were consolidated in the United States may have helped support the
faster recovery.
Reducing policy uncertainty:
Reform strategies that are well communicated and
sufficiently comprehensive to create synergies may also provide clearer guidance and
confidence about the direction and sustainability of policy decisions.
Introduction
Quantifying the long-term gains from structural reforms with some degree of
precision is not straightforward but there is at least broad consensus on the direction of
impact and the main channels of transmission. Assessing the short-term effects is more
challenging: not only are the various channels of influence more difficult to disentangle
but the macro context in which the reforms are introduced raises ambiguity as to the
direction of the impact.
Progress has been made in better understanding how reforms of product and labour
markets affect the main components of supply and demand in the short term and hence
how they impact on output gaps, external accounts and relative prices.
1
While a further
understanding of the short-run dynamic effects of reforms is still needed, it is particularly
so in the case where reforms are introduced in a context of persistently weak demand,
deflationary pressures, sizeable negative output gaps, and with only a partial support from
demand-management policies. One concern is that some reforms may have a short-term
contractionary effect on activity, prices or employment.
For instance, such concern has been raised and debated in the context of reforms
introduced at a time when monetary policy is constrained due to nominal interest
rates hitting the zero lower bound (Eggertson, Ferrero and Raffo, 2014; Fernández-
Villaverde, 2014; Vogel, 2014). More generally, the experience of southern euro area
countries, which have implemented significant reforms in a context of aenemic domestic
and external demand as well as without the support of macro policies, has led to renewed
interest in better understanding the links between reforms and demand and raised
questions about the timing, sequencing and packaging of reforms.
Against this background, this chapter reviews the main issues related to the short-
term impact of structural reforms in different macroeconomic contexts and takes stock of
existing theoretical and empirical studies. An effort is made to assess the extent of
knowledge about the short-term demand effect of specific structural reforms. This impact
can have a huge bearing on political feasibility, as transitional losses are likely to erode
popular support for reforms.
To set the scene, the next section lays out the case of reforms introduced in “normal”
times, i.e. with the economy operating close to potential and with available support of
macroeconomic policies. It identifies the main channels through which structural reforms
influence short-term activity through consumption, investment and net exports. The
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
65
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0068.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
subsequent section then focuses on the case where reforms are introduced in “bad” times,
i.e. with a sizeable negative output gap and persistently weak demand, and examines how
the more adverse environment influences the relative strengths of the main channels. The
final section goes one step further and considers cases where reforms are implemented in
a weak conjuncture and under constrained macro policies.
Structural reforms in normal times
The speed at which gains from structural reforms can be achieved depends on several
factors, even in normal times, that is when cyclical factors are not at play. First, the
credibility of announced reform packages plays a key role. Households and firms are more
likely to act early in response to reforms if they believe in the implementation and the
sustainability of the policy measures as a permanent change. Second, structural
characteristics of the economy, including the structural policy settings in place will shape
the speed at which a reform yields benefits. For instance, stronger price or wage stickiness
is likely to delay the long-term benefit of reform,
ceteris paribus,
by constraining the scope
and speed of real variables to adjust to the policy change. Third, well-functioning financial
markets play a key role in bringing forward the gains from reforms by funding the
necessary investment and allowing for income smoothing both in anticipation of future
gains and to offset temporarily income loses (OECD, 2012).
Mainstream models predict a number of channels of transmission through which
structural reforms affect the main components of demand. The key channels include
i)
wealth
or
permanent income
effects which bring forward future reform-driven income
gains in current consumption and investment, notably through rising asset prices and
positive confidence channels, ii)
disposable income and cash-flow effects
for households and
firms that are liquidity or cash-flow constrained, i.e. that do not have access to borrowing
from banks or other financial institutions iii)
uncertainty or negative confidence
effects arising
from households’ and firms’ perception of heightened (or diminished) income and profit
insecurity, which come through the precautionary motive for saving and iv) a
real interest
rate channel
which captures inter-temporal substitution effects: by making the holding of
financial assets more attractive, a rise in the real interest rate induces a decline in current
consumption in favour of higher savings. In addition, some reforms have budgetary
implications when not introduced in a budget-neutral way and will affect demand
through a fiscal multiplier effect. In what follows, the discussion considers mainly
budget-neutral reforms.
What does the evidence tell us about the short-run impact of reforms
in normal times?
A more detailed analysis of the impact of different types of reforms on short-term
demand and activity through these channels is reported in Appendix 2.1. This analysis
essentially comes from studies that simulate the impact of reforms, in particular based on
dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models. There are also a few empirical
studies looking at changes in policy indicators to define structural reform episodes and to
estimate their short-term effects (Bouis et al., 2012). In any case, the empirical literature
looking at the short-term effect of reforms mostly refer to normal times, that is when
macro policies can react to short-term demand developments. Therefore, when macro
66
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0069.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
stimulus is not available, demand effects are likely to be stronger than in normal times
after a reform. The main results from model-based and empirical analysis can be
summarised as follows:
Reforms of wage bargaining institutions, minimum wages and employment protection
legislation generally increase wage flexibility and can improve competitiveness through
downward pressures on labour costs.
Model-based analysis of this class of reforms generally indicate positive, albeit
moderate, short-term impacts on consumption and output (Cacciatore, Duval and
Fiori, 2012; Barkbu et al., 2012). One study shows that in the case of reform to
employment protection legislation, the lower firing costs may lead to an increase in
unemployment and a reduction in demand in the initial year after the reform but this
effect is quickly reversed in subsequent years (Cacciatore, Duval and Fiori, 2012).
2
In contrast, the evidence from reduced-form empirical analysis points to the absence
of significant positive impacts on demand from reforms to employment protection
legislation or wage bargaining in the first few years (Bouis et al., 2012).
Reforms of the tax and transfer systems, including the tax structure, unemployment
benefits and pension systems can boost both employment in general and the labour
force participation of specific groups:
The evidence from reduced-form analysis indicates that reducing the share of direct
taxes in overall tax revenue is found to quickly reduce unemployment, particularly for
youth, to boost female and youth participation and private investment growth (Bouis
et al., 2012). A special case of a growth-enhancing tax reform for countries in a
monetary union is the so-called fiscal devaluation, which typically takes the form of a
reduction in employer’s social security contributions combined with an increase in the
value-added tax rate. Empirical evidence points to a positive, but short-lived effect, on
employment and net exports, with long-term GDP gains reflecting essentially
productivity improvements (Johansson et al., 2008; Koske, 2013).
The evidence from both model-based simulations (e.g. Cacciatore, Duval and
Fiori, 2012) and reduced-form estimates (Bouis et al., 2012) suggests that lowering
unemployment benefits in normal conditions yields positive gains in consumption
and overall demand within 2-3 years. In most studies, reforms of unemployment
benefits are found to have a significantly stronger positive short-term impact on
demand and output than reforms to wage bargaining and employment protection
legislation.
Model-based evidence indicates that an increase in retirement age is most likely to
have a positive effect on demand in the short run via lower private saving due to life-
cycle motives (Karam et al., 2010; Barrell et al., 2009). This is corroborated by reduced-
form analysis, which shows a positive impact on consumption, investment and GDP
(Bouis et al., 2012).
The evidence on the impact of pension reforms is less clear in the cases of benefit
reductions or increases in contribution rates as their effect is similar to a fiscal
contraction, albeit a deferred one. They are found to stimulate private saving in the
short run, but may also boost investment through anticipation of reduced public debt
(Karam et al., 2010).
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
67
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0070.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Measures to improve job-search assistance and training for the unemployed or childcare
services can raise labour force participation and address labour market frictions.
However, these typically have implications for public spending and should be carefully
assessed on a budget-neutral basis to capture the effects coming from the structural
changes:
3
In the case of a budgetary-neutral reform of active labour market policies (ALMPs), the
effect is found to be similar to that of a tightening of unemployment benefits
(Cacciatore, Duval and Fiori, 2012), except that by lowering firms’ search costs or the
costs of initial training, they may stimulate labour demand somewhat more rapidly.
Product market reforms comprise essentially reductions in regulatory barriers to
competition which can lead to lower mark-ups and export prices, lower input prices (and
production costs) for downstream industries, and higher productivity through efficiency
gains and improved product quality and variety through higher investment in
innovation.
By and large, model-based evidence points to modest short-term GDP gains from
product market reforms, with more visible impacts appearing after 2-3 years
(Anderson et al., 2014); (Barkbu et al., 2012).
Evidence from reduced-form empirical analysis based on aggregate data shows no
significant short-term impact on GDP, except for a decline in the initial year, due to a
temporary drop in investment (Bouis et. al., 2012). Evidence based on sector-level data
indicates that productivity gains can be achieved after 2-3 years (Bourlès et al., 2013;
Dabla-Norris et al., 2015).
The overall results at the aggregate level may mask very different outcomes depending
on whether barriers to competition are lowered in manufacturing or service sectors,
and within services whether the reforms affect primarily network industries
(e.g. energy, telecoms and transport) or professional services, where regulatory
barriers to entry and strict conduct regulation may create strong latent demand.
Overall, the bulk of evidence suggests that the gains from pro-growth structural
reforms introduced in normal times generally exceed the potential losses even in the short
run. This is generally the case including with reforms aimed at restoring competitiveness
through lower relative production costs and prices. However, the positive effect is in many
cases modest, especially in the three-year horizon. The aggregate benefits from reforms to
unemployment benefits or pension systems (retirement age) tend to accrue more rapidly
than those from other types of reforms, in particular the ones primarily focused on raising
wage flexibility and facilitating resource reallocation. Furthermore, the modest net effect
of reforms often masks more substantial shifts in the composition of demand, not only
between domestic and foreign, but also within domestic demand, reflecting the opposite
impact that reforms have on investment and consumption in the case of some reforms.
Initial conditions and reform implementation play a role
The short-term effects of structural reform in one area may depend in part on initial
policy and institutional settings in other areas. However, the evidence is inconclusive to the
extent that it is difficult to empirically identify how interactions between policy settings
and reforms affect outcomes (e.g. Bassanini and Duval, 2009; Bouis et al., 2012). For
instance, model-based simulations by Cacciatore et al. (2012) find that gains in the
aftermath of product market reforms would be quicker if initially job protection is less
68
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0071.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
stringent and unemployment benefits are low. That is because when entry barriers fall,
new jobs are filled more quickly, minimising the risks of lengthy unemployment spells for
laid-off workers. On the other hand, findings from reduced-form empirical analysis show
that under initially weak job protection a relaxation of product market regulation leads to
higher unemployment and lower employment (Bouis et al., 2012).
How reform is implemented also matters as there can be material interaction effects
between policies:
Reform packages:
a package of labour and product market reforms that is sufficiently
broad can induce a faster adjustment and alleviate the transitional costs of certain
reforms (Anderson Hunt and Snudden, 2014; Cacciatore et al., 2012; Everaert and
Schule, 2008, Gomes et al., 2013). For instance, (Cacciatore et al., 2012) find that a
combination of product market, job protection and unemployment benefit reforms
boosts GDP, employment and wages immediately, in contrast with the effects of some of
these reforms taken in isolation.
Reform credibility:
Early announcement and credible commitment to future reforms can
help bring forward the gains from reforms by fostering investment and consumption
today. Adjémian et al., (2007) find that announcing product market reforms in advance
can trigger an immediate response by firms, accelerating the upside adjustment in
investment and output even before the reform is actually implemented.
Pace of reforms:
theoretical studies suggest that outcomes might be better if reforms were
sequenced, with product market reforms preceding labour market reforms (Blanchard
and Giavazzi, 2003). Reforming product markets first can also lower the resistance to
labour market reforms by reducing rents and facilitate their subsequent
implementation. Another political argument for gradualism is that as governments have
a fixed amount of political capital, it is best if they allocate their scarce resources to one
set of reforms at a time (Coeuré, 2014). However, too long a time lag between reforms
might not be desirable. For instance, in the case of New Zealand’s reforms in the 1980s a
significant time lag (about five years) between the liberalisation of product markets and
labour market reforms mitigated the potential overall gains from reforms (Caldera
Sánchez, de Serres and Yashiro, 2016).
Boldness of reforms:
Recent empirical analysis has found that incremental labour market
reforms tend to raise household income instability while bolder reforms do not,
increasing the risk of resistance and reversal in the former case (Cournède et al., 2015).
Structural reforms under weak demand conditions
The previous section has shown that the short-term impact of reforms on the main
components of demand often depends on the net outcomes of conflicting channels. The
short-term impact from many types of reforms depends notably on the net effect on
disposable income and cash-flow as well as the relative strength of the wealth effect versus
the precautionary motive for savings. While the bulk of evidence indicates that positive
channels dominate the negative ones in normal times, it may no longer be true when
reforms are introduced at an unfavourable stage in the business cycle.
Several factors shift the relative strengths of these channels in downturns. First, the
proportion of households and firms facing liquidity constraints can be expected to rise
along with unemployment and the tightening of credit conditions, which are often features
of downturns (Bernanke and Gertler, 1989; Fissel and Jappelli, 1990). Second, even for
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
69
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0072.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
households or firms that are not liquidity-constrained, the positive wealth effect of
reforms is likely to be weaker, especially if the downturn is associated with dysfunctions in
financial markets or the need for private-sector deleveraging. Conversely, the
precautionary motive for saving in the face of reforms is likely to be higher in a bad
conjuncture. Heightened macro-economic and policy uncertainty can lead households and
firms to postpone spending and investment “to wait and see”. Finally, the efficiency of job
matching may deteriorate in periods of persistent unemployment, given a rising share of
long-term unemployed and declines in housing prices. Some of these factors may also
condition the effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policies in supporting demand.
Reforms reducing the cost of labour and mark-ups are more likely to depress demand
during downturns
Reforms entailing a bigger risk of further depressing demand in downturns include
those whose most immediate impact is to put downward pressures on wages or mark-ups.
Product market reforms that enhance competition in formerly protected sectors usually
lead to incumbents to engage in restructuring as they seek efficiency gains to preserve
mark-ups in the face of downward pressures on prices. In turn, this leads to the
displacement of workers and capital in the short run (Blanchard, 2006). Stronger
competition also leads to the exit of least productive firms. In normal economic
conditions, displaced resources are absorbed eventually by new entrants, more
competitive firms that are expanding production or by other sectors. As a result of more
efficient resource allocation, aggregate productivity increases and as lower prices
stimulate demand employment is also expected to increase. However, when the
economy is in a slump, demand may respond less to the lower prices resulting from
competition. In such context, displaced resources are expected to remain unemployed
for longer as a bleaker profit outlook and credit constraints slows the entry of new firms
or the expansion of incumbent firms (Lee and Mukoyama, 2015; Barlevy, 2003; EC, 2013).
Reforms of wage bargaining institutions or the minimum wage have an uncertain effect
on demand in the short term during a downturn. The downward pressures on wages
may not be as rapidly compensated by employment gains and the prospects of future
productivity-related income gains as they would in normal times. This will weaken
consumer demand in the short term by lowering disposable income and strengthening
precautionary savings. An easing of employment protection legislation may lead to a
similar outcome, as the outflow from unemployment may take more time to exceed the
rise in the inflow rate than in normal times.
Reforms that drive wages down and increase product market competition can boost
competitiveness and net exports but their ultimate impact on aggregate demand may be
muted in an environment of weak external demand, such as a global downturn.
Conversely, Canada, Germany and Sweden have in the past introduced major reforms in
a context of weak domestic demand but benefited from robust global trade growth
helping to revive their economies relatively quickly (Caldera Sánchez, de Serres and
Yashiro, 2016).
Reforms raising incentives to take-up work may be contractionary during downturns
Reforms reducing the generosity of unemployment benefits (replacement rate and
duration) are effective in reducing unemployment in the short run by encouraging the
unemployed to intensify job search and accept existing offers, thereby increasing outflows
70
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0073.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
from unemployment. However, when labour demand is weak reducing unemployment
insurance could lower disposable income if no jobs are available in the short run,
negatively impacting demand. Indeed, evidence shows that when unemployment benefit
reforms are undertaken during a typical economic upturn employment increases after two
or three years (Figure 2.1). In contrast, if it is undertaken during a typical downturn, the
gain in employment is muted and even turns negative from the third year after the reform.
Figure 2.1.
The gains in employment of an unemployment benefit reform
can turn negative during a downturn
Percentage points
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
1
2
3
Economic downturn¹
4
5
Years after the shock
1. The lower (upper) line corresponds to the impact of the reduction in the initial unemployment benefit replacement rate during
economic downturn (upturn), where the economic cycle is measured through the level of the pre-reform unemployment gap (i.e. the
difference between the structural unemployment rate and the unemployment rate). The economic downturn (upturn) corresponds to
the case where the unemployment gap is set to the minimum (maximum) value within the sample.
Source:
Bouis et al. (2012).
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323963
3.0
2.5
2.0
Economic upturn¹
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
6
-2.0
Other reforms aimed at increasing labour supply are also likely to be less effective in
boosting employment and may even be contractionary when labour demand is weak. For
instance, tax reforms to remove the fiscal disincentives to second earner’s labour
participation (such as reduction of spousal tax credits) or reforms that tighten access to
disability benefits may not increase employment much if implemented in a context of
weak demand, given that the targeted groups may face even more difficulties in finding
work than the other unemployed. Instead, they may lower private consumption by
reducing household disposable income, if the measure is introduced also to generate
budgetary savings.
Indeed, one factor contributing to the higher risk of a negative impact of reforms is the
potential increase in skills and geographical mismatches, combined with the heightened
pressures on resources devoted to job-search assistance and training programmes. Even
though evidence on mismatches is not always easy to interpret, increasing mismatches are
a recurrent concern during cyclical downturns insofar as the impact differs across
industries and regions (OECD, 2011). In such a case, a depressed housing market may slow
geographical mobility, in particular where mobility is already hampered by housing and
rental market policies that create high transaction costs (Andrews et al., 2011). Also, active
labour market policies that focus on the least employable workers may be less effective in
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
71
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0074.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
downturns. Reinforcing job-search assistance may not help in this case as the probability
of reemployment does not depend so much on search efforts when there is a lack of jobs
(Boeri et al., 2015). Hence, there may be a case for shifting the focus on workers early in the
unemployment spells as the chances to find a job are higher.
4
Demand-side policies mitigate a negative impact from reforms in the short run when
demand is weak
The short-term effect of reforms in downturns and the extent to which adverse effects
can be quickly over-turned also depends on the timeliness and effectiveness of macro
policies. As regards, monetary policy, its effectiveness in stimulating aggregate demand in
the short run will in part depend on how well the financial market is functioning and on
the share of liquidity constrained households and firms. A dysfunctional financial sector
makes it harder for funds to flow to new investment opportunities, which is critical for
reforms to pay off. On the other hand, a higher share of liquidity constrained agents may
make monetary policy more effective by reducing the cost of debt services, leaving the net
effect unclear.
The effectiveness of fiscal policy may be enhanced during recessions due to higher
multiplier effects (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2013; Blanchard and Leigh, 2013). During
a recession government spending is less likely to cause an increase in the interest rate and
crowd out private consumption and investment, provided long-term fiscal sustainability is
not at risk. Similarly, the increase in the proportion of liquidity-constrained firms and
households who have a higher propensity to consume out of their income makes fiscal
policy more effective during a downturn (Galí et al., 2007), especially during a financial
crisis or when the financial sector is weak (Corsetti et al., 2012).
The largest short-run impact on aggregate demand is likely to come from government
spending measures rather than from tax cuts (e.g. Mineshima et al., 2014). This is largely
because spending measures have a direct impact on aggregate demand while tax
reductions will have a muted effect if they are saved because of, for instance, high
uncertainty. In practice, fiscal stimulus measures can be designed on both the spending
and tax side to have a rapid and substantial multiplier effect.
Among spending measures, public investment is usually found to be the most powerful
instrument (Röhn, 2010). Boosting investment in public infrastructure is a typical way to
boost demand during a downturn, as it pulls demand today, as opposed to other investments
(e.g. R&D or education) that need longer to pay off. An increase in public infrastructure
investment boosts aggregate demand via two channels, first, through the short-term fiscal
multiplier, and second, by crowding in private investment. Indeed, evidence suggests that
the positive short-term effect on demand is even stronger when there is economic slack –
less crowding out of private investment –, and monetary policy is accommodative
IMF (2014). Furthermore, the productivity gains from infrastructure shocks are significantly
higher during downturns (Dabla-Norris et al., 2015). In the European Union, removing
financial barriers and harmonising regulations, in particular in the area of network
industries, would help achieve a higher return on investment.
5
Some tax reductions can also be put in place to increase household disposable income
and boost spending in the short term. While in theory consumption should not respond much
to temporary changes in taxes, as consumers are likely to spread out their consumption
over their lifetimes, evidence suggests that in some cases temporary tax reductions can be
72
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0075.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
effective in boosting consumption spending in the short term. For instance, the income tax
rebates the US federal government enacted in 2001 and 2008 as part of its economic
stimulus packages significantly boosted spending in the short term, especially for
households with low liquid wealth or low income (Johnson et al., 2006; Parker
et al., 2013).
6
Reductions in labour taxes or social security contributions targeted to lower-
income workers, can also increase aggregate demand in the short term, as spending by this
group is closely tied to their disposable income (De Mooij and Keen, 2013).
The scope for expansionary fiscal policy may, however, be limited when long-run fiscal
constraints are significant. An increase in government spending (or tax cuts) in countries
with high debt levels may act as a signal that fiscal tightening will be required in the near
future. The anticipation of such adjustment could have a contractionary effect – through
for instance adverse effects on financial markets, interest rates and consumer spending –
that would offset the short-term expansionary effects. Ricardian behaviour, implying that
fiscal stimulus is at least partly offset through an increase in private sector savings, is
stronger the higher the level of government debt (Röhn, 2010). Moreover, in a financial
crisis, debt financed spending expansions might reinforce a negative feedback loop
between bank and government balance sheets when government debt is high.
Structural reforms under weak demand and constrained macroeconomic policies
Monetary and fiscal policies may be limited in various ways in practice, making it
difficult to smooth the transitional dynamics associated with structural reforms. This
section discusses the short-run impacts of structural reforms when weak demand
is compounded by three types of constraints: monetary policy has hit the zero lower
bound and has to rely on unconventional monetary tools; participation in a monetary
union; and fiscal policy is constrained by consolidation requirements or legislated bounds
on the fiscal deficit.
Reforms at the Zero Lower Bound (ZLB)
The zero lower bound (ZLB) brings an additional channel through which structural
reforms may lower demand and output in the short run, namely an increase in the real
interest rate. In principle, structural reforms that boost aggregate supply can, in a weak
demand environment, have a negative impact in the short run by putting downward
pressures on prices and inflation expectations if the monetary policy stimulus cannot
be increased. The inability of the monetary authority to adjust nominal interest
rates in response to falling expectations would push up the real interest rate, further
depressing rather than stimulating aggregate demand (Eggertsson et al., 2014; Fernández-
Villaverde, 2014).
In practice, this may be an issue only for a relatively limited set of reforms, mostly
those that enhance competitiveness through downward pressures on domestic production
costs and mark-ups. In the case of reforms that boost productivity through innovation and
the reallocation of resources, it is less clear how much of an increase in production
capacity can be achieved in the presence of anaemic demand, given the more limited
incentives to make the necessary investments. Even if firms do invest, given the time
required for these investments to translate into higher supply and downward pressures on
inflation expectations, economies may have moved away from the ZLB, hence allowing
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
73
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0076.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
monetary policy to react by lowering nominal interest rates. In any case, structural reforms
that raise future potential growth will also increase the natural real interest rate, thereby
reducing the stringency of the ZLB.
Furthermore, other factors will contribute to mitigate the potential adverse real
interest rate effect, even in the case of reforms that do result in rising real interest rates.
First, liquidity-constrained households will not be very sensitive to the real interest rate
increases but will benefit from falling price levels (Vogel, 2014). Second, insofar as the
reforms yield competitiveness gains, increases in net exports will help mitigate the
downward pressures on domestic demand, although this may not be sufficient to offset the
impact of higher real interest rates (Eggertsson et al., 2014). Third, reforms leading to a
price level adjustment need not create disinflationary expectations if the change is bold
and implemented in a short time period rather than incremental and introduced gradually
(Coeuré, 2014).
7
Finally, in a country with its own currency, the presumption that monetary policy is
incapable of responding to a deflationary shock at the ZLB is debatable given the now
widespread use of unconventional monetary policies and their effectiveness in boosting
demand up to a point. However, there is concern that unconventional tools could be
insufficient in a context of falling real neutral interest rates and persistent negative output
gaps, raising the risk of a downward spiral in output and inflation. In such a context, it is
a
priori
unclear whether structural reforms would reduce the risks by raising the long-term
real neutral rate or increase the risks by temporary increasing deflationary pressures. Such
concerns are of particular importance in countries that do not have their own monetary
policy, where cost-cutting structural reforms should be considered with particular
attention and be part of wider policy packages.
Reforms in a monetary union
The real interest rate channel that plays a role at the zero lower bound also operates
in a monetary union, even in normal times. With nominal rates set at the union-wide level,
reforms undertaken by one member alone to reduce relative wages and prices could lead
to a higher real interest rate. In such a case, internal devaluations can be contractionary in
the short term, especially during a period of weak demand, as the positive gains on
competitiveness and growth through a reduction in labour costs and domestic prices can
be outweighed by the negative effects from higher real interest rates.
8
Furthermore, for
countries in a monetary union, changes in the real exchange rate must come through
adjustments in relative labour costs and prices. In the case of reforms that lead to a real
exchange rate depreciation, such adjustment can be costly. This is especially the case
when inflation in the union as a whole is near zero, as real depreciation would require
reductions in nominal wages and prices.
On the other hand, fiscal devaluations – a reduction of employer’s social security
contributions combined with an increase in value-added (VAT) tax rate – is a type of measure
that may have more traction for countries in a monetary union, in particular as a means to
boost competitiveness and exports in the short run. As mentioned above, a fiscal devaluation
is a special case of a reform that shifts taxation from more distortive (direct) sources to less
distortive (indirect) ones. Such shifts have been found to yield permanent gains in output
and productivity levels in the longer run. An additional competitiveness channel operates in
the short term in the case of a monetary union, as long as not too many members introduce
a similar reform at the same time, in which case the impact on net exports of each is
74
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0077.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
diminished. With nominal wages fixed in the short run, a reduction in social security
contributions rates lowers labour costs. If the fall in labour costs is passed on into prices,
both export and domestic good prices fall leading to a boost in competitiveness. By contrast,
the higher VAT only bears on domestic and import goods, but not on exports and, therefore
will not dampen the positive effect on competitiveness and net exports.
The magnitude of the short-run benefits of a fiscal devaluation is, however, uncertain.
Model-based simulations suggest that fiscal devaluations have beneficial, but moderate,
short-term effects on net exports, output and employment (Koske, 2013). For instance, for
Portugal, a fiscal devaluation of 1% of GDP would lift net exports by 0.1% of GDP in the first
year of the reform (EC, 2011). By contrast, econometric estimates for the euro area show
much larger effects in the short run, of an immediate impact on net exports of up to 4% of
GDP for a 1% GDP shift in revenues (De Mooij and Keen, 2013). Given the uncertainty
surrounding the short-term benefits, a fiscal devaluation cannot thus be a substitute for
more fundamental reforms of labour and product markets to sustainably boost
competitiveness, but can help sustain demand in the short term.
Reforms under budgetary constraints and public finance consolidation
An expansionary fiscal policy can compensate the lack of support from monetary
policy in addressing the demand shortfall, especially for euro area countries which cannot
expect an expansionary monetary policy by the ECB to accommodate their individual
reforms. However, the fiscal space in many OECD countries has been limited either
because they have to engage in fiscal consolidation, face high debt financing costs or their
fiscal balances are bound by rules. Indeed, for several countries needing to put public
finances on a sustainable path, fiscal policy has been contractionary until recently.
Negative impacts of fiscal consolidation are likely to be more pronounced during weak
demand times as fiscal multipliers are significantly larger during economic recessions
than expansions (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2013).
Tight fiscal conditions and a limited ability of the government to cushion the
transitory costs for losers may increase some of the contractionary effects of structural
reforms in the short run (Duval, 2008). For instance, reforms that increase flexibility in
employment protection and wage formation can negatively impact private consumption if
governments cannot mitigate the increase in income risks with an expansion of
unemployment benefits or active labour market policies (ALMPs). Fiscal constraints are
particularly a concern if they undermine the ability of countries to carry out structural
reforms that entail higher spending (e.g. in ALPMs, R&D or childcare), less revenue
(e.g. labour taxes), or up-front public spending, for instance through transfer schemes, to
compensate reform losers. Furthermore, they can also reduce the feasibility of growth-
enhancing structural policies that could enhance short-term as well as long-term growth,
such as high-quality infrastructure investment.
The urgency in the fiscal situation may bias structural reforms toward those that
realise fiscal savings rapidly, but may be contractionary in the short run. An example of
such reforms is a reduction in welfare expenditure that for example took place in
New Zealand in the early 1990s amid the strong need for fiscal consolidation (Caldera
Sánchez, de Serres and Yashiro, 2016). While a strong pressure to reduce public spending
may facilitate the implementation of reforms to public-sector administration and services,
the success of the reforms in terms of raising cost-effectiveness and quality may be
undermined if priority needs to be given to immediate budgetary savings.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
75
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0078.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Reforms likely to boost short-run demand when demand is weak and macroeconomic
policies are constrained.
Some reforms can be expansionary even under relatively weak demand and
constrained macroeconomic policies if they encourage investment or generate rapid
job gains:
Product market reforms that ease supply constraints.
Reducing entry barriers in service
sectors with large pent-up demand and low entry costs can unleash the entry of new
firms, boosting investment and job creation relatively fast. Simulations for Italy show
that half of the gains of reforms that facilitate the entry of new firms in the service sector
would be realised within three years (Forni et al., 2010). Case studies have also found
that liberalisation in sectors such as retail trade and telecommunications often resulted
in fast decreases in prices and increases in output and employment (Bertrand and
Kramarz, 2002; Faini et al., 2006; Skuterud, 2005). Another example is professional
services that remain heavily regulated in many countries (i.e. legal, accounting,
engineering and architecture professions), especially as regards entry regulations
(Figure 2.2). As such reforms reduce the relative price of non-tradables, their impact on
net exports will be similar to that of an internal devaluation, with additional positive
effects due to the fact that non-tradables are a major input into tradables.
Reforms that improve confidence or reduce uncertainty regarding future economic conditions:
By
improving the sustainability of public finances, credible reforms in pensions and
healthcare systems can boost consumption today through wealth effects and reduced
need for precautionary saving. Empirical studies have, indeed, shown that the risk of
unexpected healthcare expenditure is an important motive of precautionary saving, and
policies that improve access to medical insurance increase consumption (Gruber and
Yelowitz, 1999; Jappelli et al., 2007; Bai and Wu, 2014). However, such reforms may be less
effective in reducing precautionary saving if the volatility of income and the risk of
unemployment is very high (Mody et al., 2012). Product market reforms that reduce the
economy-wide administrative burdens on firms and reduce the initial cost of starting-up
a business can also improve expectations on future business conditions. For instance,
simulations suggest that reforms to reduce the initial costs of starting-up a business
implemented during the crisis in Italy, Portugal and Spain have significantly raised the
birth rate of firms in those countries (Ciriaci, 2014).
Overall, the review of the evidence on the effects that specific reforms can have on
demand when introduced in a difficult macro context allows for a tentative hierarchy of
reforms to be drawn based on their likely effectiveness (Table 2.1). The measures most
likely to bring short-term benefits even in a bad conjuncture are those aimed at raising
investment in knowledge-based capital, including through infrastructure spending and tax
structure reforms, as well as those focusing on helping unemployed workers to find jobs,
including through higher mobility. In fact, the effectiveness of these measures even tends
to be stronger in a difficult context than in normal times. In the specific case of the euro
area, one reform that is likely to pay-off in a bad conjuncture is the shift in the tax
composition from direct to indirect sources.
Other reforms may have effects that do not necessarily differ much when introduced
in a context of weak demand as compared to a normal conjuncture, which means in most
cases modest short-term benefits. These include measures to raise competition in
professional services sectors or to increase the retirement age. On the other hand, an
76
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0079.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
easing of employment protection on regular contracts or reforms of collective wage
bargaining arrangements are more likely to entail short-term costs if introduced in a
difficult context. The same is true for reforms of pension systems, if they involve
reductions in benefits or increases in contributions.
Figure 2.2.
Regulation in professional services
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
Entry
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
Conduct
Conduct
Conduct
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
Entry
Conduct
USA¹
Weaker
Equal
Stronger in EMU
Weaker
Weaker
Weaker
Stronger
Equal
Equal
Stronger
5.0
2013
2003
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
Entry
Entry
Entry
Entry
0.0
0.0
BEL
CAN
FRA
DEU
ITA
JPN
NLD
ESP
SWE
CHE
GBR
1. 2008 data instead of 2013.
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323978
Table 2.1.
Expected short-term effects of specific reforms on demand
Effect on demand
in normal times (1)
Change in effect relative
to (1) due to downturns
but with support
from macro policies (2)
Weaker
Equal
Weaker
Weaker
Weaker
Weaker
Stronger
Equal
Weaker
Stronger
Change in effect relative
to (2) due to constrained
macro policies (3)
Reduction in regulatory barriers to competition in network industries
Reduction in regulatory barriers to entry in professional services
and retail trade
Shift in tax composition from direct to indirect sources
Reform of collective wage bargaining arrangement and minimum wages
Easing of employment protection legislation on regular contracts
Reform of unemployment benefits
Strengthening of job search assistance, training and wage subsidy programmes
Reforms of pension systems: Increasing retirement ages
Reforms of pension systems: Reducing benefits or raising contributions
Raising incentives for investment in knowledge-based capital, including
through infrastructure spending
Increase
Increase
Small increase
Small increase
No effect or small decrease
Increase
Increase
Increase
No effect or small decrease
Increase
Notes
1. A large number of studies looking at the short-term effect of structural reforms using either a
model-based or reduced-form empirical analysis are reported in Appendix 2.1. More complete
information, including the review of case studies, can be found in Caldera Sánchez, de Serres and
Yashiro (2016).
2. The latter owes to the fact that while the destruction of jobs is immediate, job creation tends to be
gradual as time is needed to match firms and available workers.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
77
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0080.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
3. Model-based simulations indicate that unfunded increases in spending on active labour market
policies or childcare services have stronger positive effects on demand within the first two years
than after five years (Barkbu et al.; 2012).
4. Insofar as competition for jobs is fiercer in weaker labour markets, active labour market
programmes that focus on some workers may improve the search ability of those workers by
reducing the relative job-search success of others (Crépon et al. 2013; Michaillat, 2012). A meta-
analysis of impact estimates of studies of active labour market programmes by Card, Kluve and
Weber (2015) suggests that they are more likely to show positive impacts in a recession.
5. Evidence by Fournier (2015) finds that lower heterogeneity in product market regulations between
two countries leads to greater bilateral FDI.
6. The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 gave tax rebates to most US
households over a ten-week period from late July to the end of September 2001. The Economic
Stimulus Act of 2008 consisted primarily of a USD 100 billion programme of tax rebates to
approximately 130 million US tax filers.
7. Indeed, using model-based simulations, a number of studies have found that the short-run
negative impact of product and labour market reforms can be fairly small (or non-existent) and
short-lived (only one year after reforms) (Gomes, 2014; Vogel, 2014).
8. In the case where private sector debt deleveraging is a major factor contributing to the weakness
of demand, it has been shown that under the presence of collateral constraints and long-term debt
contracts product market reforms may have a positive impact on output and employment even in
the short run despite their deflationary effect (Andrés, Arce and Thomas, 2014). However, the
effect of labour market reforms in the same circumstances are less favourable.
Bibliography
Adjémian, S. et al. (2007), “Variantes en Univers Incertain”, Économie et Prévision, Special Issue.
Anderson, D., B. Hunt, and S. Snudden, (2014), “Fiscal Consolidation in the Euro Area: How Much Pain
Can Structural Reforms Ease?”
Journal of Policy Modelling
36 (2014) 785-799.
Anderson, D., B. Barkbu, L. Lusinyan and D. Muir (2014), “Assessing the Gains from Structural Reforms
for Jobs and Growth”, Chapter 7 of
Jobs and Growth: Supporting the European Recovery,
IMF.
Andrés, J., O. Arce and C. Thomas (2014), “Structural Reforms in a Debt Overhang”,
Documentos de
Trabajo,
No. 1421, Banco de Espana.
Andrews, D., A. Caldera Sánchez and Å. Johansson (2011), “Housing Markets and Structural Policies in
OECD countries”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 836, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http:/
/dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kgk8t2k9vf3-en.
Anton, J. and R. Muñoz de Bustillo (2011), “The Impact of the Minimum Wage on Spanish Youth:
Evidence From A Natural Experiment”,
Technical report, Munich Personal RePEc Archive Paper
33488.
Arpaia, A., W. Roeger, J. Varga and J. in’t Veld (2007), “Quantitative Assessment of Structural Reforms:
Modelling the Lisbon Strategy”
European Economy Economic Papers
282, European Commission.
Auerbach, A.J., Y. Gorodnichenko (2013), “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion”, in Alberto
Alesina and Francesco Giavazzi edited
Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis,
University of Chicago
Press.
Bai, C. and B. Wu (2014), “Health Insurance and Consumption: Evidence from China’s New Cooperative
Medical Scheme”,
Journal of Comparative Economics,
42 450-469.
Barlevy , G. (2003), “Credit Market Frictions and the Allocation of Resources Over the Business Cycle”
Journal of Monetary Economics,
50, 1795-1818
Barkbu, B., J. Rahman and R. Valdés (2012), “Fostering Growth in Europe Now”
IMF Staff Discussion Note
SDN/12/07. IMF. Washington.
Barrell, R., I. Hurst and S. Kirby (2009), “How to Pay for the Crisis or Macroeconomic Implications of
Pension reforms”
Discussion paper
No. 333, National Institute of Economic and Social Research.
Bassanini, A. and R. Duval (2009), “Unemployment, Institutions, and Reform Complementarities:
Re-Assessing the Aggregate Evidence for OECD Countries”,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
Vol. 25,
No. 1, pp. 40-59.
78
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0081.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1989), “Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations”
American
Economic Review,
79, March 1989, 14-31.
Bertrand, M. and F. Kramarz (2002), “Does Entry Regulation Hinder Job Creation? Evidence from the
French Retail Industry”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics,
117(4), pp. 1369-1413.
Blanchard, O. (2006), “Comments” in T. Boeri, M.Castanheira, R. Faini, and V. Galasso edited
Structural
Reforms Without Prejudices,
Oxford University Press.
Blanchard, O. and D. Leigh (2013), “Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers”
NBER Working Paper
18779.
Boeri, T., P. Cahuc and A. Zylberberg (2015), “The Costs of Flexibility-Enhancing Reforms for
Individuals: a Literature Review,”
OECD Economics Department Working Papers
No. 1227, OECD
publishing,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrs558c5r5f-en.
Bouis, R., O. Causa, L. Demmou, and A. Zdzienicka (2012), “The Short-Term Effects of Structural
Reforms: An Empirical Analysis”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 949, OECD
Publishing,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k9csvk4d56d-en.
Bouis, R., O. Causa, L. Demmou, and R. Duval (2012),”How quickly Does Structural Reform Pay Off? An
Empirical Analysis of the Short-Term Effects of Unemployment Benefits Reform”,
IZA Journal of
Labor Policy 2012,
1:12.
Bourlès, R., G. Cette, J. Lopez, J. Mairesse, and G. Nicoletti (2013), “Do Product Market Regulations In
Upstream Sectors Curb Productivity Growth? Panel Data Evidence for OECD Countries”,
The Review
of Economics and Statistics,
95(5), pp.1750-1768.
Cacciatore, M., R. Duval and G. Fiori (2012), “Short-Term Gain or Pain? A DSGE Model-Based Analysis of
the Short-Term Effects of Structural Reforms in Labour and Product Markets”,
OECD Economics
Department Working Papers,
No. 948, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k9csvkkr3xn-
en.
Caldera Sánchez, A, A. de Serres and N. Yashiro (2016), “Reforming in a difficult macro context: what
should be the priority”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 948, OECD Publishing, Paris,
forthcoming.
Card, D. J. Kluve, and A. Weber (2015), “What Works? A Meta Analysis of Recent Active Labour Market
Program Evaluations”, IZA Discussion Papers No. 9236.
Ciriaci, D. (2014), “Business Dynamics and Red Tape Barriers”,
Economic Paper
No 532, European
Commission.
Coeuré, B. (2014), “Structural Reforms: Learning the Right Lesson from the Crisis”, Speech given at the
Economic conference, Latvijas Banka, Riga, 17 October 2014.
Corsetti, G., A. Meier and G. Müller (2012), “What Determines Government Spending Multipliers?”,
CEPR Discussion Papers
No. 9010.
Cournède, B., P. Garda, P. Hoeller and V. Ziemann (2015), “Effects of Pro-Growth Policies on the
Economic Stability of Firms, Workers and Households”,
OECD Economic Policy Papers,
No. 12, OECD
Publishing, Paris.
Crépon, B., M. Dejemeppe and M. Gurgand (2005), “Counseling the Unemployed: Does It Lower
Unemployment Duration and Recurrence?” IZA DP No. 1796.
Crépon, B., E. Duflo, M. Gurgand, R. Rathelot and P. Zamora (2013), “Do Labour Market Policies have
Displacement Effects? Evidence from a Clustered Randomized Experiment”,
The Quarterly Journal of
Economics
128 (2): 531-580.
Cribb, J., Emmerson, C. and G. Tetlow, (2014), “Incentives, Shocks or Signals: Labour Supply Effects of
Increasing the Female State Pension Age in the UK”,
IFS Working Paper
W13/03.
Dabla-Norris, E., S. Guo, V. Haksar, M. Kim, K. Kochhar, K.Wiseman, and A. Zdzienicka (2015), “The New
Normal: A Sector-Level Perspective on Growth and Productivity Trends in Advanced Economies”,
IMF Staff Discussion Note
SDN/15/03. IMF. Washington.
de Mooij, R. and M. Keen (2013), “Fiscal Devaluation and Fiscal Consolidation: The VAT in Troubled
Times” in A. Alesina and F. Giavazzi edited
Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis,
University of Chicago
Press.
Duval, R. (2008), “Is There a Role For Macroeconomic Policy in Fostering Structural Reforms? Panel
Evidence from OECD Countries Over the Past Two Fecades”,
European Journal of Political Economy
24
(2008) 491-502.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
79
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0082.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Eggertsson, G., A. Ferrero, and A. Raffo, (2014),”Can Structural Reforms Help Europe?”
Journal of
Monetary Economics
61(2014)2-22.
European Commission (2013), “The Growth Impact of Structural Reforms”,
Quarterly Report on the Euro
Area,
Vol. 12, No. 4.
ECB (2015), “Progress with structural reforms across the Euro Area and their possible impacts”,
Economic Bulletin, Issue 2 / 2015, European Central Bank, Frankfurt. European Commission (2011),
“The Economic Adjustment Programme for Portugal, First Review – summer 2011”,
European
Economy Occasional Papers,
No. 83.
Everaert, L. and W. Schule (2008), “Why It Pays to Synchronize Structural Reforms in the Euro Area
Across Markets and Countries”.
IMF Staff Papers
55(2).
Faini, R., J. Haskel, G. Navaretti, B., C. Scarpa and C.Wey(2006), “Contrasting Europe’s Decline: Do
Product Market Reforms Help?”, in Boeri, T., M. Castanheira, R. Faini, and V. Galasso edited
Structural Reforms Without Prejudices,
Oxford University Press.
Fernández-Villaverde, J. (2014), “Discussion of “Can Structural Reforms Help Europe?” by Gauti
Eggertsson, Andrea Ferrero and Andrea Raffo”,
Journal of Monetary Economics
61(2014), 23-31.
Fiori, G., G. Nicoletti, S. Scarpetta and F. Schiantarelli (2012), “Employment Effects of Product and
Labour Market Reforms: Are There Synergies?”,
The Economic Journal,
Vol. 122 (558), February. Fissel,
G.S. and T. Jappelli (1990), “Do Liquidity Constraints Vary over Time? Evidence from Survey and
Panel Data: Note”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
Vol. 22, No. 2 (May, 1990), pp. 253-262.
Forni, L., A. Gerali and M. Pisani. (2010), “Macroeconomic Effects of Greater Competition in the Service
Sector: the case of Italy”,
Macroeconomic Dynamics,
2010, 1-32.
Fournier, J.M. (2015), “The Negative Effect of Regulatory Divergence on Foreign Direct Investment”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrqgvg0dw27-en.
Galí, J., J. D. López-Salido and J. Vallés (2007), “Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on
Consumption”,
Journal of the European Economic Association,
Vol. 5(1), pages 227-270.
Gruber, J. and A. Yelowitz (1999), “Public Health Insurance and Private Savings”,
Journal of Political
Economy,
Vol. 107, No. 6 (December 1999), pp. 1249-1274.
Goolsbee, A. and C. Syverson (2008), “How do Incumbents Respond to the Threat of Entry? Evidence
from the Major Airlines”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics,
123(4), pp. 1611-1633.
Gomes S., P. Jacquinot, M. Mohr and M. Pisani (2013), “Structural Reforms and Macroeconomic
Performance in the Euro Area Countries: A Model-Based Assessment”,
International Finance
16(1),
23-44.
Gomes, S. (2014), “Euro Area Structural Reforms in Times of a Global Crisis”,
Banco de Portugal Working
Paper 2014.
IMF (2014),
The World Economic Outlook,
October 2014, IMF, Washington.
Jappelli, T., L. Pistaferri and G.Weber (2007), “Health Care Quality, Economic Inequality and
Precautionary Saving”,
Health Economics.
16: 327-346.
Johansson, Å., et al. (2008), “Taxation and Economic Growth”,
OECD Economics Department Working
Papers,
No. 620, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/241216205486.
Johnson, D.S., J.A. Parker and N.S. Souleles (2006), “Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates
of 2001”,
American Economic Review
96 (5): 1589-610.
Karam, P.D., D. Muir, J. Pereira and A. Tuladhar (2010), “Macroeconomic Effects of Public Pension
Reforms”
IMF Working Paper
No. 10/297, IMF.
Koske, I. (2013), “Fiscal Devaluation – Can it Help to Boost Competitiveness?”,
OECD Economics
Department Working Papers,
No. 1089, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
5k3z2dckn2bw-en.
Kluve J. (2010), “The effectiveness of European active labour market programs”,
Labour Economics,
17,
pp. 904-918.
Kramarz, F. and T. Philippon (2001), “The Impact of Differential Payroll Tax Subsidies on Minimum
Wage Employment”,
Journal of Public Economics,
82, pp. 115-146.
Kugler, A. and G. Pica (2008), “Effects of Employment Protection on Worker and Job Flows: Evidence
from the 1990 Italian Reform”,
Labour Economics,
15, pp. 78-95.
80
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0083.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Lee, Y. and T. Mukoyama (2015), “Entry and Exit of Manufacturing Plants over the Business Cycle”
European Economic Review,
Vol. 77, issue C, pp. 20-27.
Martins, P. (2014), “30.000 Minimum Wages: The Economic Effects of Collective Bargaining Extensions”,
IZA Discussion Paper
No. 8540.
Michaillat, P. (2012), “Do Matching Frictions Explain Unemployment? Not in Bad Times”,
American
Economic Review
102(4): 1721-1750.
Mineshima, A., M. Poplawski-Ribeiro and A. Weber (2014), “Size of Fiscal Multipliers”, in Cottarelli, C.,
P. Gerson and A. Senhadji (eds.),
Post-crisis Fiscal Policy,
The MIT Press.
Mody, A., F. Ohnsorge and D. Sandri (2012), “Precautionary Savings in the Great Recession”
IMF Working
Paper
12/42.
Mourougane, A. and L. Vogel (2008), “Speed of Adjustment to Selected Labour Market and Tax
Reforms”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 647, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://
dx.doi.org/10.1787/234217500715.
Neumark, D., I. Salas, and W. Wascher (2013), “Revisiting the minimum wage-employment debate:
Throwing out the baby with the bathwater?”
NBER Working Paper
No. 18681.
OECD (2011),
Economic Outlook May 2011,
OECD Publishing, Paris
OECD (2012),
Economic Surveys: Euro Area 2012,
OECD Publishing. Paris
Orsini, K. and S. Vila Nunez (2014), “The Impact of The Spanish Labour Market Reform on the On-The-
Job Search Rate”,
ECFIN Country Focus
Vol. 11 (7).
Parker, J.A., N.S. Souleles, D.S. Johnson and R. McClelland (2013), “Consumer Spending and the
Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008”,
American Economic Review 2013,
103(6): 2530-2553.
Röhn, O. (2010), “New Evidence on the Private Saving Offset and Ricardian Equivalence”,
OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 762, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
5kmft7qb5kq3-en.
Rosholm, M. and M. Svarer, (2008), “The Threat Effect of Active Labour Market Programmes”,
Scandinavian Journal of Economics,
110(2), pp. 385-401.
Skuterud, M. (2005), “The Impact of Sunday Shopping on Employment and Hours of Work in the Retail
Industry: Evidence from Canada”,
European Economic Review,
49(8), pp. 1953-78.
Uusitalo, R. and J. Verho (2010), “The Effect of Unemployment Benefits on Re-Employment Rates:
Evidence from the Finnish Unemployment Insurance Reform”
Labour Economics
17: 643-654.
Van Ours, J.C. and M. Vodopivec (2006),”How Shortening the Potential Duration of Unemployment
Benefits Entitlement Affects the Duration of Unemployment: Evidence from a Natural
Experiment”,
Journal of Labor Economics
24: 351-378.
Varga, J., W. Roeger, and J. in’t Veld (2013), “Growth Effects of Structural Reforms in Southern Europe:
the Case of Greece, Italy, Spain and Portugal”,
European Economy Economic Papers
511. European
Commission.
Varga, J. and J. in ’t Veld (2014), “The Potential Growth Impact of Structural Reforms in the EU: A
Benchmarking Exercise”,
European Economy Economic Papers
541, European Commission.
Vogel, L. (2014), “Structural Reforms at the Zero Bound”
European Economy Economic Papers
537,
European Commission.
Von Below, D. and P. Thoursie (2010), “Last in, First Out? Estimating the Effect of Seniority Rules in
Sweden”,
Labour Economics,
17, pp. 987-997.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
81
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0084.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
APPENDIX 2.1
Detailed analysis on the impact of reforms
in normal times
This appendix provides a summary of the expected effects of specific reforms on
short-term activity and a review of the findings from selected studies. The information is
reported in the table below, which describes some of the channels through which reforms
affect the main components of demand and reports the results obtained from DSGE-type
model-based analyses and empirical analyses. The specific reforms considered in the
overview are the following:
Labour market reforms to enhance wage flexibility and facilitate labour resource reallocation:
They include reforms of
wage-bargaining institutions
to raise the responsiveness of wage
adjustments to local labour market conditions; reductions in
minimum wages
to improve
the jobs prospect of low-skilled workers; reforms of
employment protection legislation
again to facilitate relative wage adjustments as well as the reallocation of resources across
firms and industries; By and large, they can also be thought of as measures to boost
competitiveness through downward pressures on domestic production costs, in particular
labour costs.
Reforms to stimulate labour force participation and improve matching:
This covers
essentially
reforms of the transfer systems,
including
unemployment benefits
and other
forms of income support for non-working individuals, but also measures to reduce the
financial disincentive to labour force participation of specific groups such as women
(including childcare support) and older workers (pension
systems).
Also covered are
measures to increase the scope and effectiveness of
active labour market policies,
in
particular job-search assistance and training programmes.
Reforms to boost product market competition:
This comprises essentially
reductions in
regulatory barriers to competition
which operates through state control of business
operations, various legal and administrative barriers to start-ups, protection of incumbents
as well as via obstacles to foreign trade and investment.
Reforms aimed directly at enhancing the productive capacity and productivity of the business
sector:
These cover
tax structure reforms
that encourage corporate activity, financial
incentives for business innovation and investment in public infrastructure.
Model-based assessments
The model-based simulations covered in the table are taken from studies that make
use of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models for the analysis of specific
82
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0085.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
reforms. In particular, many studies have been conducted by international organisations
on the basis of their core DSGE models.
European Central Bank:
Studies based on the Euro Area and Global Economy model
(EAGLE) include ECB (2015)
[1]
and Gomes et al. (2013)
[2].
European Commission:
Studies based on different versions of the QUEST model include
EC (2013)
[3];
Vogel (2014)
[4],
Varga and in’t Veld (2014)
[5],
Varga, Roeger and in’t
Veld (2013)
[6]
and Arpaia et al.,(2007)
[7].
IMF:
Studies based on the Global Integrated Monetary and Fiscal model (GIMF) include
Anderson et al.,(2014),
[8]
Barkbu et al., (2012)
[9],
Everaert and Schule (2008)
[10],
Karam
et al., (2010)
[11].
OECD:
Studies using a DSGE-type model include Cacciatore, Duval and Fiori (2012)
[12]
and Mourougane and Vogel (2008)
[13].
The DSGE approach has the advantage of describing the response of the macro-
economy to reforms within a consistent general equilibrium framework and to illustrate
the transmission channels. DSGE model-based simulations also allow for assessing issues
that are relevant today, but have little historical precedent, such as the zero lower bound on
nominal interest rates in many advanced economies.
A direct comparison of model-based results across studies requires caution given that
the same structural reform can be captured in different ways depending on the
characteristics of the model. For instance, a reform of employment protection can be
captured by a simultaneous reduction in firing costs and in the bargaining power of
individual workers in one model, while it is captured as an increase in total factor
productivity in another model. Important channels may also be missing in the modelling
framework. In particular, the precautionary motive for saving and hence the adverse
confidence effects arising from higher job and income volatility cannot be easily featured
in such frameworks. Finally, to ensure models are tractable, analyses are typically limited
to a small set of structural reforms, (most often product and labour market reforms that
reduce price and wage mark-ups), which remains highly stylised.
Empirical analysis based on aggregate or sectoral data
There have been very few empirical studies that have used reduced-form equations to
estimate the impact of reforms with a focus on the short-run effect using cross-country
aggregate data or sectoral data:
Studies using aggregate data
include Bouis et al., (2012)
[14],
Fiori et al., (2012)
[15],
de
Mooji and Keen (2012)
[16].
For example, Bouis et al., (2012) estimate average impulse
responses in terms of employment and output after one to five years following different
types of structural reforms (e.g. product market reforms), based on a panel data of
OECD countries over the period 1983 to 2007.
Studies using sectoral data
include Bourlès et al., (2013)
[17]
and Dabla-Norris et al., (2015)
[18].
The latter estimates the impulse response mostly in terms of productivity after
three years and five years following several types of structural reforms, based on a panel
data of 23 industries in 11 advanced economies over the period 1970-2007.
While the estimation of reduced-form equations allows for a flexible empirical
specification and the assessment of the impact of a wide array of reforms, it does not
identify the channels through which reforms affect output or employment. Furthermore,
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
83
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0086.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
the often incremental nature of reforms makes it difficult to clearly identify the short-run
impacts. Estimations are also prone to specification error. For instance, a failure to control
for the possible complementarity across reforms can bias the estimated impacts of a given
reform (Bassanini and Duval, 2009
[19]).
Empirical analysis based on micro studies
Another branch of studies infers the impacts of structural reforms by investigating
and looking at event studies and assessing the change in the variables of interest before
and after a specific episode of reforms. Such event studies often employ a difference-in-
difference or regression discontinuity estimation approach that exploits a micro panel
dataset covering the periods before and after the reforms. Some studies also infer general
tendencies on the effectiveness of specific reforms from a meta-analysis of the existing
empirical evidences.
Studies on wage bargaining/minimum wage reforms
include Neumark et al., (2013)
[20],
Anton and Muñoz de Bustillo (2011)
[21]
and Martins (2014)
[22].
Studies on EPL reforms
include Kugler and Pica (2008)
[23],
Von Below and Thoursie (2010)
[24]
and Orsini and Vila Nunez (2014)
[25].
Kugler and Pica (2008) assess the consequences
of Italy’s legislation that strengthened the protection of regular employment for firms with
less than 19 employees.
Studies on unemployment benefits reforms
include van Ours and Vodopivec (2006)
[26]
and
Uusitalo and Verho (2010)
[27]
studying the effect of duration and replacement rate on
unemployment duration from the reforms in Slovenia and Finland, respectively.
Studies on ALMPs
include Crépon et al., (2005)
[28],
Rosholm and Shaver (2008)
[29]
which
report significant impact on unemployment duration. Less favourable finding is reported
for instance by Crépon et al., (2013)
[30].
Kleuve (2010)
[31]
provide a meta-analysis of
previous assessments.
Studies on pension reforms
include Cribb et al., (2014)
[32]
that observed the consequences
of a UK reform raising women’s pension eligibility age on their labour supply and
unemployment rate.
Studies on product market reforms
include Golsbee and Syverson (2008)
[33],
Bertrand and
Kramarz (2002)
[34]
and Skuterud (2005)
[35].
Also, Faini et al., (2006)
[36]
provide case
studies of liberalisation and privatisation in different sectors in three European countries.
While event studies allow for richer and more rigorous inference on reform impacts
than the two previous methods, their focus on a specific policy in a given time and a
country makes it difficult to generalise their findings. Also the aggregate macroeconomic
implications are not always clear when the analysis focuses on very specific reforms and
markets.
84
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0087.png
2.
REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Table A2.1.
The impact of structural reforms in normal times: a synthesis
Reform area
Collective wage
bargaining arrangement
and minimum wages
Channels of transmission
Evidence on short-term impacts
Model-based evidence:
Employment gains exceed short-term real wage losses. Small
and temporary negative impact on inflation
([1], [2]).
Moderate increase in consumption, investment and GDP.
Small net effect on the current account. ([1],
[2]).
Evidence from empirical analysis:
Aggregate data:
Empirical analysis confirms short-term gains
in employment, consumption and GDP of reduction in the excess
coverage of collective wage agreements. Less evidence of impact
on investment.([14])
Micro studies:
Most studies find negative employment effects
of minimum wages, especially for youth and low-skilled ([20],
[21]).
Effect of extending collective wage bargaining is found
to be similar to minimum wage.([22])
Model-based evidence:
Small positive effect on consumption despite initial
and short-lived rise in unemployment. More rapid positive effect
on investment and GDP. No visible effect on net exports.([12])
Evidence from empirical analysis:
Aggregate data:
No evidence of significant impacts on
consumption or GDP but mild positive effect on private investment
([14]). No evidence of significant positive effect in the five-year
horizon. Some evidence of negative effects on productivity
and output at the 2-3 years horizon ([18]).
Micro studies:
Increase in lay-off rates is generally found
to exceed the rise in hiring rates in the short term leading
to higher unemployment ([23],[24]). Some evidence of increase
in on-the-job search by employees on open-ended contracts
following recent reform in Spain ([25]).
Model-based evidence:
Positive gains GDP, investment and to a lesser extent consumption.
Decline in consumption for LC-households more than offset
by increases for others through wealth effects ([5]). Unemployment
falls as employment rises more rapidly than labour force. Small
positive contribution from net exports ([12]).
Evidence from empirical analysis:
Aggregate data:
Positive impact on employment across all age
and gender groups, as well as on consumption and GDP ([14]).
Micro studies:
Reduction in replacement rates and/or duration
lead to a short-term increase in employment among those closer
to benefit exhaustion ([26],
[27]).
Raises responsiveness of wages to local labour and product
markets.
Puts downward pressures on real wages, in particular
for low-skilled workers but raises labour demand with
an ambiguous effect on aggregate disposable income
and consumption.
If reduced costs lead to higher mark-ups for firms,
this may raise investment among firms dependent
on internal financing.
If the lower costs are largely and quickly passed through
lower prices, then net exports may contribute to short-term
demand gains.
Employment
protection legislation
on open-ended contracts
Reduces wage bargaining power of employees on regular contracts.
Increases both hiring and lay-off rates by reducing expected costs
of terminating a match. Boosts long-run productivity
by encouraging job-to-job mobility and facilitating reallocation
of workers across firms and sectors.
Net impact on
consumption
ambiguous: Impact on disposable
income depends on employment and wages. Higher wealth
through future productivity and income gains but potentially
higher precautionary saving if increased instability
in employment.
Impact on
investment
and on
net export similar
to that of reform
of wage bargaining. Potential wage moderation effect of reform
reflected in improved competitiveness and/or higher mark-ups.
Unemployment benefits:
Extension of the benefit
coverage, stronger
conditionality
and tapering of benefits
along the spell
Lowers benefits and the reservation wage of the unemployed
and puts downward pressures on wages.
Raises incentives to take-up jobs and labour demand. Stimulates
job creation without affecting job destruction.
Net effect on disposable income and
consumption
depends on
speed of employment gains and strength of wealth effect arising
from higher future income.
Speed of rise in employment depends on extent of vacancies left
unfilled due to high reservation wage. Employment gains further
accelerated if reform is accompanied by lower social security
contributions.
Households not directly involved by the reform may raise
precautionary savings to compensate for reduced generosity
of benefits.
Active labour market
policies:
Job search assistance,
training programmes
and hiring or wage
subsidies
Improves matching efficiency and facilitates reallocation of labour;
Model-based evidence:
raises employment in the short run and productivity
Impact of budgetary neutral reforms of ALMPs is similar
in the long run.
to that of reduction in unemployment benefit, except for more
rapid increase in labour demand ([5],
[12]).
If unfunded, raises disposable income and can be perceived
by firms as a reduction in non-wage costs. Effect on consumption
Unfunded increases in ALMP spending have stronger
and investment works like fiscal expansion and depends on size
positive effects on demand in the first two years than after
of multiplier.
five years ([8],
[9]).
Evidence from empirical analysis:
Aggregate data:
Increases in ALMP spending, after controlling
or cyclical influences, are found to raise aggregate employment
but not consumption or GDP ([14]).
Micro studies:
Most studies (though not all) find evidence
that active job search assistance and mandatory participation
to programmes help reduce the duration of unemployment
in the short term ([28],
[29], [31]).
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
85
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0088.png
2. REFORM PRIORITIES IN A DIFFICULT MACRO CONTEXT
Table A2.1.
The impact of structural reforms in normal times: a synthesis
(cont.)
Reform area
Pension systems:
Increase
in the retirement age,
reduction in pension
benefits or rise
in contributions
Channels of transmission
Evidence on short-term impacts
Model-based evidence:
Positive effect on consumption and GDP in the case of increases
in the retirement age. Evidence less clear in the case in the cases
of benefit reductions or rises in contributions as their effect
is similar to a (deferred) fiscal contraction. They are found to lower
consumption and investment but to have a positive effect on net
exports, with a net small or negative impact on GDP ([11]).
Evidence from empirical analysis:
Aggregate data:
An increase in the retirement age has a positive
impact on consumption, investment and GDP ([14]).
Micro studies:
Some studies find a non-negligible positive
short-term impact on employment rates of affected population
but also a rise in unemployment ([32]).
Raising the retirement age increases pension wealth by extending
working lives. Raises
consumption
for non-liquidity constrained
households, if confident about prospects of keeping jobs at age
close to pension.
Reducing pension benefits has the opposite effect if workers seek
to maintain pension wealth and retirement age. Negative effect
on
consumption
amplified if benefit reductions applied
to all current pensioners.
Increasing contribution rates reduces disposable income
and/or mark-ups depending on whether measure is borne
by workers or firms. May be partly offset by a positive
wealth effect if contributes to future pension funding.
Product market:
Reduction in regulatory
barriers to competition
Stronger competition reduces mark-ups and export prices, lowers
Model-based evidence:
input prices and production costs in downstream industries
Modest short-term GDP gains with more visible impacts after
and raises productivity through process (efficiency gains)
2-3 years ([8],[9]). Slowly rising gains in investment
and product innovation.
and (to a lesser extent) consumption (prompted by real wage gains)
and negative contribution from net exports. Employment rises
Upward pressures on investment through future profitability gains
in services but falls in manufacturing. One study finds consumption
and entry of new firms but also downward pressures through lower
falling in the 2-3 years horizon due to higher real interest rate ([12]).
mark-ups (for cash-flow-constrained incumbents).
Evidence from empirical analysis:
Upward pressures on consumption through positive disposable
income (lower prices and gains in employment) and wealth effects.
Aggregate data:
No significant short-term impact on GDP
[14].
Downward pressures if lower mark-ups and prices lead to high real
Evidence from sector-level data indicates productivity gains
interest rates (e.g. in monetary union) or if business restructuring
within 2-3 years on average
[17]
but one study finds that the impact
initially lead to high job turnover and income instability and hence
on productivity in professional services is negative in the first
higher precautionary saving.
2-3 years but turns positive after 5 years
[18].
Rapid employment gains in sectors with strong pent-up demand
Micro studies:
Industry-specific analyses provide evidence of rapid
and low entry costs.
price declines in response to reduction in entry barriers ([33]).
Rapid gains in productivity, employment and output are found
in industries such as retail trade or telecommunication ([34],
[35],
[36]).
In other industries, a significant productivity gain
but a decrease in employment is reported, as firms enhance
competitiveness by reducing initial over-manning ([36]).
Reductions in capital and labour taxation raise employment and
Model-based evidence:
investment
until initial return to both production factors is restored.
Increases in investment and net exports only partly offset
by a decline in consumption, leading to moderate short-term gains
Positive impact of employment gains and lower income taxes on
in GDP ([6]). Since the gains in employment due to competitiveness
disposable income offset by higher price level from increased VAT.
are temporary, the increase in employment is stronger in the short
Higher price effect likely to dominate in the short run, entailing a
than long term ([8]).
reduction in
consumption.
Shift in relative price of domestic and foreign goods will boosts
net Evidence from empirical analysis:
exports
unless quickly offset by nominal exchange rate adjustment.
Aggregate data:
A decline in the share of income tax in total tax
revenues is found to have a positive impact on investment
but no significant effect on consumption or GDP ([14]). Strong
positive impact found on net exports in euro area countries
but smaller effect in non-euro area OECD countries ([16]).
Tax structure:
Shift in the composition
of taxation from direct
(capital, labour)
to indirect sources
(VAT, property,
inheritance)
Note:
The numbers in brackets in bold script indicate the studies cited earlier in the Appendix 2.1. For instance, [1] corresponds to
ECB (2015).
86
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0089.png
Economic Policy Reforms 2016
Going for Growth Interim Report
© OECD 2016
Chapter 3
From GDP to average household
income: A look at the transmission
channels
This chapter reviews the association between GDP and living standards from the
perspective of the average household, focusing on the income dimension. It
discusses the mechanisms through which GDP growth “trickles down” to household
sector income with a view to assessing whether and to what extent such
mechanisms are amenable to policy intervention. To do so, the chapter provides a
proper assessment of the link between income generated from GDP and income
distributed to households, which implies examining income distribution between
household and the non-household sectors of the economy.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli
authorities. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights,
East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
87
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0090.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
From GDP to average household income: A look at the transmission channels
Main findings
Real GDP has tended to grow by more than real household income in the majority of
OECD countries between the mid-1990s and 2013.
This growth gap is partly due to factors having little policy traction, such as differential
developments between the price of domestic output and the price of consumption
faced by domestic households, driven notably by terms-of-trade effects: consumption
prices have tended to rise relative to output prices in most OECD countries over the
period, the only exceptions being commodity exporters such as Norway, Australia
and Canada.
The household income share of GDP, simply defined as the ratio of nominal household
disposable income over nominal GDP, has been stable over the period, on average across
OECD countries, but with cross-country heterogeneity, with for instance a large decline
in Austria and Korea and a large increase in the Slovak Republic and Finland.
Developments in the household income share of GDP reflect developments in the
distribution of production income between the household and non-household sectors of
the economy. This can in turn be assessed by looking at household labour, capital and
secondary income shares of GDP:
About half of OECD countries have experienced a decline in the labour share of GDP, in
particular Portugal, Slovenia and Japan, while the other half have experienced an
increase, though of a lower magnitude.
The vast majority of OECD countries have experienced a decline in the household
capital income share of GDP, in particular Belgium and Italy, while only a few
countries, including Portugal and the United States, have seen an increase.
Concomitant declines in the labour and household capital income shares of GDP could
suggest that a rising share of profits has been retained by the corporate sector instead
of being redistributed to the household sector.
The decline in the household capital income share of GDP could be overstated to the
extent that the corporate sector has been reducing the use of dividends in favour of
alternative profit redistribution mechanisms to shareholders, such as share buybacks
– and that associated capital gains are not recorded in macroeconomic data.
The vast majority of OECD countries experienced an increase in the household
secondary income share of GDP over the past two decades, i.e. in the share of
production income that is being redistributed by the government to the household
sector. However, this largely reflects the increases in public income transfers
over the early phases of the crisis, which cushioned household incomes from the
fall in GDP.
88
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0091.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
In addition, the increase in the secondary household income share could be overstated
to the extent that it does not allow for measuring the negative effect of a shift in the tax
composition from direct to indirect sources, in particular consumption taxes; yet
associated reforms have been quite frequent across the OECD over the last two decades.
The analysis did not reveal clear links between the changes in income distribution at the
macro-level and the rise in income inequality within the household sector experienced
by many OECD countries over the last decades.
Introduction
GDP per capita is a widely used measure of living standards and a key headline indicator
of economic performance. The emphasis given to GDP growth relies on the assumption that
higher GDP per capita is associated with rising living standards for most households. This
view has been increasingly challenged. On its own, GDP per capita falls short of accurately
measuring people’s wellbeing, even from a narrow material living standard perspective.
1
In
that respect, one issue that has received little attention is the extent to which GDP growth
“trickles down” to households. Yet this is of primary relevance from a wellbeing perspective,
as recognised for instance by the Stiglitz Commission (Stiglitz et al. 2009).
2
Assessing the links between GDP growth and household income growth is also of
particular interest for the understanding of developments in income inequality.
3
How GDP
growth generates income for the household sector, and the composition of this income, are
important factors for inequality. For instance, the distribution of income between labour
and capital does matter for understanding income inequality. However, assessing this may
have become more complex than in the past as households have more diverse sources of
income and there is considerable dispersion within the categories of income. It is thus
important to go beyond the classic concept of labour share to understand inequality,
notably by enlarging the concept to the different types of household income sources.
Given these challenges, the chapter analyses the association between GDP and living
standards from the perspective of the average household, focusing on the income
dimension. The idea is to better understand the mechanisms through which GDP growth
“trickles down” to household sector income. This justifies a proper assessment of the link
between income generated from GDP and income distributed to households, which implies
examining income distribution between household and non-household sectors of the
economy.
4
The chapter is structured as follows: the first section describes the measurement
framework used throughout the chapter, based on the System of National Accounts (SNA).
The second section delivers a snapshot overview of developments in real household
income compared to GDP over the last two decades. It also sheds light on the drivers that
are, in principle, least amenable to policy intervention, e.g. differential developments
between the prices faced by households and those of domestic output and primary income
flows with the rest of the world. The third section analyses how income generated from
domestic production is distributed between the household and non-household sectors of
the economy, in particular the general government and the corporate sector, with a focus
on the functional income distribution, in other words on income distribution between
labour and capital. The fourth section delivers an assessment of the link between income
distribution across household and non-household sectors and income distribution within
the household sector.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
89
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0092.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Adjusted Household Disposable Income: definition and cross-country patterns
For the purpose of this chapter, the level of resources accruing to the household sector
is gauged through adjusted household disposable income (AHDI) from the National
Accounts, combining information on a large number of market and non-market income
sources (including income derived from hidden or underground activities).
5
This is
considered as the best available measure of material conditions from a cross-country
perspective, although it may not be fully reflective of households’ command over economic
resources (Box 3.1).
6
For ease of exposition, Figure 3.1 provides a simplified overview of
income flows between the household and non-household sectors of the economy as
measured in the SNA.
Box 3.1.
Adjusted household disposable income
from the national accounts: limitations
Adjusted household disposable income from the national accounts includes some non-
cash items that households may not recognise as part of their income:
Employer contributions to social security, and employer payments for private pensions,
healthcare, and other benefits do not enter the pay-packets of workers but are part of
household income in the national accounts. This is because compensation of employees
is defined in the national accounts with a view to explicitly measuring the full cost of
labour as a factor of production. For example, whereas in the real world social
contributions are paid directly by the employers to the social funds and are never seen
by the employees, the national accounts treat them as part of wages paid to households.
As a result, the “compensation of employees” item includes all contributions, including
imputed contributions. In this chapter, this item is included in the definition of labour
income.
Homeowners-occupiers do not receive an income from the housing services that they
provide to themselves. Yet an income is imputed in the national accounts, called
“imputed rent”. This income flow is estimated based on actual rents of comparable
accommodations, but national statistical offices apply different methodologies in this
respect. In this chapter, this item is included in the definition of household capital
income.
Households benefit from the services supplied by general government, such as
healthcare, education, housing, recreational and cultural services, but associated
transfers are not spendable. The national accounts attribute to household income an
imputed value for such services, i.e. “social transfers in-kind”, to distinguish them from
cash transfers. Their measurement is problematic given the non-market nature of these
services (and could be very different from the household point of view). Indeed, the
national accounts valuation of social transfer in-kind is based on the price of inputs
used in the production process, hence on expenditure by general government. In this
chapter, this item is included in the definition of household secondary income.
The non-recording of capital gains and losses is another limitation of the household
income account. Agents face a potential holding gain or loss whenever the price
fluctuates. A distinction is made between “unrealised” and “realised” gains and losses. A
typical unrealised gain or loss occurs when the price of a share held by an agent changes
but when the agent has not yet sold his holdings. By contrast, realised gains (or losses)
result from the sale of the shares. The proceeds received from the holding gain are in most
cases subject to taxation.
90
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0093.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Box 3.1.
Adjusted household disposable income
from the national accounts: limitations
(cont.)
Households in OECD countries have on several occasions in the recent past benefited
from rises, or suffered from falls, in the prices of these two types of assets; for instance
during the stock market bubble toward the end of the 1990s, and the steep drop in stock
prices starting in 2000 and more recently, during the housing market bubble. Asset price
changes induce positive or negative wealth effects, allowing household to consume more
or less than their disposable income. These so-called “wealth effects “may play a major
role in households’ perception of own economic resources, but they cannot be inferred
from national accounts.
Against this background, household capital income as defined in this chapter based on
the SNA excludes capital gains and losses, whether realised or not. Income from housing
assets is included insofar as it reflects actual and imputed rents (the latter accruing to
homeowner occupiers). Financial income covers interest received on households’ financial
investments and dividends paid by companies to households but, due to the exclusion of
capital gains, other forms of financial income are excluded from the SNA. Such is the case
of share buy-backs, which have been playing a growing role in corporate profit
redistribution strategy. This income transfer from firms to households is not recorded in
the household income account.
Finally and related to the previous point, the impact of the external sector on household
income in the SNA covers essentially primary income, that is, income from work,
dividends and interest. Financial transactions with the rest of the world do not affect
household income nor do they affect GDP. By contrast, such transactions affect the balance
sheet of resident institutional sectors as defined in the SNA: households, the general
government and corporations. As a result, external macroeconomic imbalances stemming
from e.g. net borrowing
vis à vis
the rest of the world do not influence the distribution of
income between the general government and households but may eventually influence
the distribution of wealth and savings between the general government and households,
an issue that goes beyond the scope of the current chapter.
AHDI is obtained by adding two broad components: 1) the flows that make up
individuals’ primary (or market) income: labour income (compensation of employees and
labour income of the self-employed – the latter being part of “mixed income”) and capital
income (income derived from financial assets, essentially dividends and interest, included
under “property income” and from non-financial assets, essentially actual and imputed
rents, included under “operating surplus”, as well as self-employment capital income – the
latter being part of “mixed income”); and 2) secondary or redistribution income: the cash
and in-kind social transfers that households receive from governments (such as public
education and healthcare services) net of the current taxes on income and wealth and the
social security contributions paid by households. In this respect, consumption taxes are
not considered among taxes paid by the household sector in the SNA. They appear in the
difference between GDP at market prices and GDP at factor costs (i.e. GDP at market prices
minus taxes on production and imports). AHDI can be expressed both in gross and net
terms, with the difference being households’ consumption of fixed capital.
7
The bulk of
this chapter relies on the gross measure to make the link with GDP, which is a gross
concept, and because of better cross-country comparability.
8
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
91
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0094.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.1.
Income flows between the household and non-household sectors:
a simplified overview of the System of National Accounts (SNA)
GNI
at market prices
(=GDP at market prices +
primary incomes received
from the rest of the
world-primary incomes paid
to the rest of the world)
GDP at market prices
GDP at factor cost
(= GDP at market prices – taxes on
production and imports)
Corporate
sector
Household sector
(including self-employed firms)
Government
sector
Pro
Compensation of
employees
per t
y in
c om
e
mp
m
loy
e
la
nt
bo
u
c
r in
om
e
Operating surplus
Self-employment
capital income
Social benefits and
transfers + social
transfers in kind
Current taxes on
income and wealth
Se
l f- e
Labour income
1
Compensation of employees
(= wages and salaries +
employers’ social security
contributions)
Self-employment labour
income (under “mixed
income”)
Household Capital Income
Actual and imputed rents
(“operating surplus”)
Capital income from financial
assets (“property income”)
Self-employment capital income
(under “mixed income”)
Household Secondary Income
Social benefits and transfers +
social transfers in kind – current
taxes on income and wealth
Household primary income
2
(market income)
+
Household secondary income
= Adjusted Household Disposable Income (AHDI)
1. In the case of self-employed, only overall (mixed) income is reported. In order to split their income into the labour
and capital components, the labour income of self-employed is imputed by assuming that their annual wage is
the same as for the average employees of the whole economy. The capital income is then approximated by taking
the difference between mixed income of self-employed and their imputed labour income.
2. Household primary income corresponds to income derived from market activities and is sometimes referred to as
“market income”.
The limitations associated with the definition of household income in the SNA should be
kept in mind and differences across countries and over time should therefore be interpreted in
light of different institutional arrangements. Nevertheless, the SNA system relies on a number
of harmonising procedures implemented with a view to maximising cross-country
comparability. Importantly for the purpose of this chapter, such procedures ensure a very good
level of comparability for the household income account. Comparability may be more
problematic for the household financial and balance sheet accounts and this may limit cross-
country analysis of household wealth and savings. One of the most relevant issues in this
respect is the recording of pension contributions and pension benefits of employees between
capitalisation and pay-as-you go systems (Box 3.2). This chapter performs a comparative
analysis of household income but not of household wealth. As a result, the analysis should not
be affected by differences in institutional arrangements governing countries’ pension systems,
reflecting harmonising adjustments applied within the household income account.
For the average household, the main income component is compensation of employees,
followed by self-employment income
9
and transfers in-kind provided by the government
(Figure 3.2, Panel A). When the AHDI decomposition is simplified into labour and capital
income (which make up primary income) and secondary income, labour income appears as
the most important income source in most countries (Figure 3.2, Panel B).
92
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0095.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Box 3.2.
How pension and social security funds are recorded
in the household income accounts
One can distinguish two main types of pension systems: those functioning as “savings
plans” (also called “full capitalisation systems”) and those functioning as “transfer plans”
(also called “pay-as-you-go systems”). If the pension plan is a savings plan (often called a
“pension fund”), each employee contributes to a fund from which his or her future pension
benefit will be paid. The national accounts record all contributions to the plan (both those
of employers and of employees) as a form of savings by employees (i.e. an increase in the
pension asset of employees) and pension benefits as “dis-saving” (i.e. a decrease of the
pension asset of retirees).
By contrast, a pension system is a transfer plan (rather than a savings plan) when the
pension contributions of current employees are used to pay the pension benefits of current
retirees. In this case (which is typical of social security pension systems), the national
accounts deduct pension contributions from income (and thus they are also deducted
from savings), and pension benefits are considered part of income (and thus included in
savings). Pension contributions are included in current transfers paid by households and
pension benefits in current transfers by households.
To harmonise the measure of household income, the SNA framework records pension
contributions and benefits of savings plans (i.e. pension funds) as if they were transfer
plans (i.e. social security).
*
As a result, cross-country comparisons of household income
accounts are in principle unaffected by cross-country differences in the institutional
settings governing the funding of pension systems. In this chapter, pension benefits and
contributions are included in the definition of household secondary (net) income, being
considered as transfer income.
* This (transfer) income flow from the corporate sector to the household sector is not shown in the simplified
overview of income flows between SNA sectors (Figure 3.1). In principle, it would appear as a secondary
income flow from the corporate sector (pension funds) to the household sector.
Tracking income growth from the household perspective and explaining
the gap
vis-à-vis
GDP growth
From a welfare perspective, household income growth is best measured in real
consumption terms (i.e. changes in nominal household income should be deflated with
consumption prices and not with output prices which are used to deflate GDP). This is
what ultimately matters to assess household consumption possibilities as a function of
production income. Tracking growth from the household income perspective thus starts
with the simple comparison between growth in GDP and growth in real adjusted household
income with a view to assessing the extent to which income generated from GDP trickles
down to the average household. This comparison suggests that since the mid-1990s and in
particular over the pre-crisis period, GDP has tended to grow more than households’
economic resources in many OECD countries (Figure 3.3, Panels A and B). The gap was
particularly large in Korea and Ireland. In fact, only a few countries with large commodity-
producing sectors experienced stronger gains in real household incomes relative to GDP
(e.g. Norway and Australia).
The growth gap between GDP and household incomes temporarily narrowed during
the initial phase of the crisis, as automatic stabilisers (i.e. rises in net income transfers
from government to households during recessions) and discretionary income-support
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
93
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0096.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.2.
Components of adjusted household disposable income
1
(AHDI)
As a percentage of gross adjusted household disposable income, 2013
A. Detailed overview
200
175
150
125
100
75
50
25
0
-25
FIN
ITA
IRL
SVN
GRC
GBR
KOR
HUN
MEX
NLD
SVK
ESP
CZE
DNK
SWE
DEU
CHE
USA
JPN
CHL
POL
PRT
FRA
AUT
EST
BEL
NZL
-50
Compensation of employees
Property income
Current taxes on income, wealth etc.
Operating surplus
Social transfers in kind
Mixed income
Social contributions and transfers
200
175
150
125
100
75
50
25
0
-25
-50
B. Simplified overview
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
Labour income
Capital income
Secondary income
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
MEX GRC PRT ITA POL SVK ESP USA FIN CZE FRA DEU GBR AUT HUN SWE JPN IRL SVN EST BEL NLD DNK CHE
1. The data refer to the components of gross adjusted household disposable income based on the System of National Accounts. The sum
of compensation of employees, property income, operating surplus and mixed income (i.e. labour and capital income of the self-
employed) represents primary or market income. Social contributions and transfers and social transfers in kind minus current taxes
on income and wealth represent secondary income (income that the government redistributes to households directly or indirectly).
See Figure 3.1 for a definition of the respective components shown in panels A and B. Components do not exactly sum to household
gross adjusted disposable income due to statistical discrepancies. Data refer to 2014 for Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, Italy, the
Netherlands, Portugal and Sweden; 2012 for New Zealand and Switzerland. For Chile and Korea, the component “Operating surplus”
includes mixed income.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933323992
measures introduced to moderate the fall in aggregate demand at the early stages of the
recession had the effect – to a varying extent across countries – of protecting households’
disposable incomes from recession-induced losses in market incomes (i.e. income from
work and capital) (Figure 3.3, Panel C).
10
However, with the effect of automatic stabilisers
and anti-crisis measures tapering off, the diverging trends resumed as GDP growth largely
outpaced household income growth in 2009-13 (Figure 3.3, Panel D). Indeed, more than one
third of OECD countries experienced contracting household real disposable incomes in
post-crisis years, reflecting in part the impact of fiscal consolidation.
94
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0097.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.3.
Real annual growth rates of GDP and adjusted household disposable income
1
(AHDI)
Average annual growth rates, percentage
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
ITA
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
A. 1995-2013
SVK
NOR
NZL
USA
AUS
KOR
FIN
GBR
SVN
CZE
FRA
CHE CAN SWE
DNK
HUN
JPN
DEU NLD AUT
BEL
ESP PRT
IRL
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
B. 1995-2007
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
NOR AUS
3.0
USA NZL GBR
2.5
SWE
2.0
FRA CAN
NLD
1.5
PRT ESP
CHE
AUT
1.0
DNK
JPN
0.5
BEL
DEU
ITA
0.0
-0.5
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-10
-9
-8
-7
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
EST
IRL
3.5
4.0
GDP per capita
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
SVK
HUN SVN
CZE
FIN
KOR
IRL
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
GDP per capita
C. 2007-09
CHL
POL
KOR
BEL
NOR
SVK
CAN PRT
ESP CZE
SWE SVN
FIN
NLD AUS
DNK GRC DEU
CHE
FRA
ITA JPN GBRUSA NZL AUT
HUN
MEX
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
1
2
3
4
5
6
GDP per capita
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
-6
-7
GRC
-8
-9
-9
-8
-7
-6
-5
-4
D. 2009-13
MEX
NZL
NOR
SWE JPN POL
CHE AUS
FIN
DNK FRA CZE CAN USA DEU
HUN
SVK
SVN NLD GBR AUT
BEL
PRT
IRL
KOR
EST
CHL
ITA
ESP
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
-6
-7
-8
-9
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
GDP per capita
1. Gross adjusted household disposable income and GDP are expressed in USD, constant prices and constant PPPs, OECD base year 2010.
Gross adjusted household disposable income is deflated with the deflator for actual individual consumption while GDP per capita is
deflated with the GDP deflator. For panel A, data refer to 1995-2014 for Canada, Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the Netherlands,
Norway, Portugal and Sweden; 1995-2012 for Switzerland; 1999-2013 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain and the United Kingdom; 1999-2012
for New Zealand; for panel B, data refer to 1999-2007 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain, the United Kingdom and New Zealand; for panel C,
data refer to 2008-09 for Chile; for panel D, data refer to 2009-14 for Canada, Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the Netherlands,
Norway, Portugal and Sweden; 2009-12 for New Zealand and Switzerland.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324003
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
95
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0098.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
The contribution of relative price movements to the growth gap
Differential developments between GDP and household income in real terms may
reflect differential developments between consumption and output prices (Figure 3.4, Panels
A and B). Indeed, different price indices are used to convert nominal values in real values,
respectively the GDP deflator for domestic output and the consumption deflator for
household income.
The comparison between real and nominal terms shows that a very large part of the
growth gap between GDP and real household income is due to relative price effects over the
period under consideration (i.e. 1995-2013). Most OECD countries experienced declines in
output relative to consumer prices while the only ones experiencing increases in output
prices relative to consumer prices are commodity-exporters such as Australia, Canada and
Norway (Figure 3.4, Panel C) – pointing to terms-of-trade effects. In nominal terms, growth
in household income was remarkably close to GDP growth.
Such relative price effects could reflect a number of factors, including:
Secular declines in the relative price of investment reducing output prices more than
consumer prices, and, related, secular declines in the price of tradable relative to non-
tradable products, especially in services.
Temporary increases in commodity prices generating favourable terms-of-trade effects
in commodity-exporting countries over the period under consideration.
Increases in consumer prices resulting from tax reforms shifting the burden from direct
to indirect taxes and in particular to VAT over the period under consideration.
11
The contribution of cross-border income flows to the growth gap
Part of the gap between growth in GDP and household income may also reflect that
between the income produced within the territory and the income received by residents.
Household incomes are measured for resident units, regardless of whether these incomes
are obtained within the national territory or not. In addition to the income received from
the production within the territory, which is included in GDP, residents may receive income
derived from production outside the territory, which is excluded from GDP.
12
Adding the
net primary income flows with the rest of the world to GDP allows for coming closer to the
resources that can trickle down to resident households. These primary incomes consist of
wages and salaries, property income (interest and dividends) and taxes and subsidies on
production. The final result is Gross National Income (GNI), which can be considered as a
“bridge” measure: GNI is, unlike GDP, an income-based concept and not a production based
concept, since it includes income derived from production abroad and excludes the value
of output repaid to foreign factors of production. As a result, assessing developments in
household income relative to GNI instead of GDP underscores the potential role of primary
income flows with the rest of the world.
13
A look at the evolution of GNI suggests that developments in primary income flows
with the rest of the world also account for part of the growth gap between real GDP and real
household income (Figure 3.5, Panels A and B), but to a much lesser extent than relative
prices. Weaker GNI relative to GDP growth seems to have contributed to weaker growth of
household income relative to GDP in e.g. Belgium and Korea (Figure 3.5, Panel C). At the
opposite end of the spectrum, stronger GNI relative to GDP growth seems to have
contributed to stronger growth of household income relative to GDP in e.g. Australia and
Norway, which suggests that associated foreign income inflows were also driven by rising
96
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0099.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.4.
Comparing growth in GDP and in AHDI: the role of relative prices
1
1995-2013
A. Real annual average growth rates in GDP and in AHDI, percentage
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
4.0
3.5
3.0
NOR
AUS
2.5
NZL
2.0
USA
SVN
FIN
GBR
CAN SWE CZE
1.5
FRA
NLD
DNK
HUN
1.0
ESP
DEU CHE
0.5
PRT BEL AUT
JPN
0.0
ITA
-0.5
-1.0
IRL
-1.5
-2.0
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
SVK
KOR
3.0
3.5
4.0
GDP per capita
B. Nominal annual average growth rates in GDP and in AHDI, percentage
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
GDP per capita
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
JPN
USA FIN NZL
IRL SWE
ESP
GBR
FRA DNK
CAN
NLD
DEU
BEL AUT PRT
CHE ITA
AUS
CZE
KOR
NOR
SVN
SVK
HUN
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
Output prices
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-1.5
-1.0
C. Annual average change in output and consumer prices, percentage points
HUN
SVN
SVK
IRL
CHE
AUS CZE
ITA
ESP KOR
CAN
PRT GBR
SWE FIN
FRA AUT
BEL
DEU
DNK
USA
NLD
NOR
NZL
JPN
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
Consumer prices
1. For panel A, gross adjusted household disposable income per capita and GDP per capita are expressed in USD, constant prices and
constant PPPs, OECD base year 2010. Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita is deflated with the deflator for actual
individual consumption (consumer prices) while GDP per capita is deflated with the GDP deflator (output prices). For panel B, gross
adjusted household disposable income per capita and GDP per capita are expressed in current prices. Data refer to 1995-2014 for
Canada, Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal and Sweden; 1995-2012 for Switzerland; 1999-2013
for Hungary, Ireland, Spain and the United Kingdom; 1999-2012 for New Zealand.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324010
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
97
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0100.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.5.
Comparing growth in GDP and in AHDI: the role of primary income flows
with the rest of the world
1
Percentage, 1995-2013
A. Real annual average growth rates in GDP and in AHDI
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
4.0
3.5
3.0
NOR
AUS
2.5
NZL
CZE
2.0
USA
CAN
FIN
GBR
1.5
CHE
SVN
FRA
NLD SWE
DNK
1.0
HUN
PRT DEU
AUT
0.5
ESP JPN
BEL
0.0
-0.5
ITA
-1.0
IRL
-1.5
-2.0
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
SVK
KOR
3.0
3.5
4.0
GDP per capita
B. Real annual average growth rates in GNI and in AHDI
Gross adjusted household disposable income per capita
4.0
4.0
SVK
3.5
3.5
3.0
3.0
NOR
2.5
2.5
NZL
AUS
CZE
2.0
2.0
FIN SWE
SVN KOR
GBR
1.5
1.5
FRA CHE
HUN
AUT USA CAN
1.0
1.0
ESP
DEU
NLD
0.5
0.5
PRT DNK
JPN BEL
0.0
0.0
ITA
-0.5
-0.5
-1.0
-1.0
IRL
-1.5
-1.5
-2.0
-2.0
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Gross national income per capita
Gross national income per capita
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
C. Real annual average growth rates in GNI and in GDP
4.0
3.5
KOR SVK 3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
3.5
4.0
GDP per capita
AUS
HUN
NZL
CAN SWE
SVN
DEU
CHEUSA
DNK
FIN CZE
GBR
NLD AUT
ESP
IRL BEL
PRT
JPN FRA
NOR
ITA
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
1. Gross national income (GNI), Gross domestic product (GDP) and gross adjusted household disposable income are expressed in USD,
constant prices and constant PPPs, OECD base year 2010. For gross adjusted household disposable income, PPPs and deflators are
those for actual individual consumption of households while for GDP and GNI, PPPs and deflators are those for GDP. Data refer to 1995-
2014 for Canada, Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal and Sweden; 1995-2012 for Switzerland;
1999-2013 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain and the United Kingdom; 1999-2012 for New Zealand.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324022
98
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0101.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
commodity prices over the period under consideration (Figure 3.5, Panel C). Nevertheless,
in most cases, developments in primary income flows with the rest of the world do not
seem to explain much of the wedge between real GDP and real household income
dynamics: indeed, a number of countries (for example Ireland and Italy) experienced
equivalent growth gaps in terms of either GDP or GNI.
A wrap-up on the growth gap of household income vis-à vis GDP
This section has looked at the respective contributions of relative prices and cross-
border income flows to the growth gap between real household disposable income and real
GDP. It finds that the former explains a substantial portion of the gap while the
contribution of the latter is negligible except for a few countries. Taking these factors into
account, the rest of the chapter focuses on the factors potentially driving a wedge between
AHDI and GDP, both expressed in nominal terms.
In order to do so, the chapter introduces the household income share of GDP, a
synthetic measure of the growth dividends from the household perspective, which is
simply defined as the ratio of nominal AHDI to nominal GDP. A significant decline in the
ratio would indicate that a substantial portion of the growth gap in real terms remains to
be explained, even after taking into account relative price effects. As it turns out, such ratio
has been stable over the last two decades, on average across OECD countries (Figure 3.6,
Panels A and B).
14
Nevertheless, this stability masks differential trends across countries,
with marked declines – of around 6 percentage points – in Austria, Korea, Belgium and
Norway and marked increases – of around 10 and 5 percentage points – in the
Slovak Republic and Finland, respectively (Figure 3.6, Panel B).
The finding of a broad stability on average is formally confirmed by econometric
analysis: the elasticity of adjusted household disposable income to GDP is not statistically
different from unity, once controlling for country-fixed effects and other factors.
15
This
incidentally implies that the wide cross-country differences in the level of household
income shares of GDP (Figure 3.6, Panel A) tend to persist over time. They are likely due to
factors such as the degree of countries’ openness, their trade structure and industrial
composition.
16
Income distribution between the household and non-household sectors
This section provides an exploratory analysis of the household income share along its
components with a view to understanding the channels through which production income
(GDP) translates into household income. This requires assessing the link between GDP and
the three household income components defined in the first section: labour and capital
(i.e. primary income); and secondary income, i.e. income redistributed from the
government. This allows for shedding some light on income distribution between the
household and non-household sectors of the national economy, in particular the
government and corporate sectors.
The labour share of GDP
Labour represents the main source of overall income for the average household
(Figure 3.2). Capital income also plays a role, but it represents a comparatively minor
income source and, depending on the mode of capital remuneration, may be redistributed
from the corporate to the household sector with a lag.
17
As a result, the functional income
distribution, i.e. the division of income generated by domestic production between the
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
99
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0102.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.6.
The household income share of GDP
1
Nominal terms
A. Household income as a percentage of GDP
100
2013
90
80
70
60
50
FIN
AUS
NOR
GBR
NLD
ITA
IRL
DEU
SWE
GRC
HUN
MEX
KOR
DNK
CHE
SVN
CAN
USA
SVK
ESP
CZE
EST
JPN
FRA
AUT
PRT
POL
NZL
CHL
BEL
40
1995
2007
90
80
70
60
50
40
100
B. Changes in the ratio of household income to GDP, percentage points, 1995-2013
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
AUT KOR BEL NOR ITA HUN CAN PRT NLD CZE SVN DNK CHE DEU ESP NZL FRA AUS GBR IRL SWE USA JPN FIN SVK
Average
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
1. Gross domestic product (GDP) and household income are expressed in current prices. For 1995, data refer to 1999 for Hungary, Ireland,
Spain, New Zealand and United Kingdom. For 2013, data refer to 2014 for Canada, Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the
Netherlands, Norway, Portugal and Sweden; 2012 for New Zealand and Switzerland.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324036
remuneration of labour and that of capital, hence the aggregate labour share, is likely to
influence in the short to medium term the division of income generated by domestic
production between the household and non-household sectors.
Declines in the labour share have been documented over the past decades, even
though the magnitude of such decline has been the object of controversies.
18
A wide array
of research has investigated the drivers of this trend, focusing in particular on the role of
globalisation along with that of changing policies and institutions. The main conclusions
from this literature are summarised in the appendix. This section delivers a new
assessment of developments in the labour share on the basis of SNA data.
The labour share is defined as the GDP share of income that is received by workers, be
they employees or self-employed, in the form of labour compensation. Proper
measurement of the aggregate labour share requires addressing a number of issues, such
as estimating the division of income between labour and capital for the self-employed
(Box 3.3).
100
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0103.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Box 3.3.
Measuring the aggregate labour share
The aggregate labour share is typically computed by dividing gross labour compensation by
GDP at factor costs. There are several measurement issues associated with this calculation:
Measurement issues in specific industries.
In some industries, measurement of the labour
share is problematic, which could impact on that of the aggregate labour share. For
example, the value added of the public administration, as measured in the national
accounts, is often equal to the sum of labour costs. As a consequence the labour share
may be dramatically inflated in the public sector. Outside the public sector, in industries
such as mining and fuel production, value added fluctuates quite a lot while wages do
not, thereby inducing large fluctuations in the labour share.
Labour compensation of the self-employed:
the revenue of the self-employed is a mix of
labour
and capital incomes, which are typically not identified separately in the national
accounts and appear under the item “mixed income”. This requires imputing
labour
income for the self-employed. There is wide consensus that the remuneration of
proprietor’s labour should be assumed equal to the average compensation of wage
earners (Arpaia et al., 2009).
*
To analyse the mechanism whereby income generated by aggregate production trickles
down to households, the labour share must be defined at the aggregate level by assuming that
wage of the self-employed is the same as for the average employee of the whole economy.
In order to gauge the robustness of the analysis, the aggregate labour share can be
confronted to alternative comparable datasets, relying on recent work published by
Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014). The correlations between the aggregate labour share
estimates of this chapter and those of Karabarbounis and Neiman are very close to one:
they range between 0.90 and 0.95 for the levels and between 0.78 and 0.85 for the annual
changes between 1995 and 2010.
Finally, this chapter uses as a denominator of the labour share of GDP at market prices and
not at factor costs. This is necessary to analyse the link between GDP and household material
living standards with a view to getting closer on the purchasing power of household incomes.
This also takes into account the fact that government absorbs part of the value added (see
European Commission, 2007, for a discussion). In any case, this measurement choice has no
impact on results since the correlation between the labour share measured in terms of GDP at
market prices and factor costs is higher than 0.97 both in levels and differences.
An additional analytical issue is the treatment of those at the top of the pay distribution;
those are often more akin to entrepreneurs, employed by shareholders and rewarded with
stock options which are an entitlement based on future profits and reduce the future
returns to other shareholders. OECD (2012) delivered adjusted labour shares, by excluding
the top 1% earners’ income from the computation of the wage bill for seven countries over
the period 1990 to mid-2000s: this shows that the drop in the “adjusted”
labour
share – or
the labour share for the bottom 99% of income earners – is even greater than the drop in
the “unadjusted”
labour
share, especially for the United States and Canada, due to an
increase in the wage share of top income earners. One recent study estimates that the
labour share excluding the contribution of top incomes has declined so much in the US
that it is lower today than at any other time since the 1930s (Giovannoni, 2014). This may
reflect the surge in CEO and other top executives’ compensation, one of the main driving
forces beyond the broader well-documented finding of an increase in the share of national
income accruing to top incomes (Atkinson et al. 2011, Fernandes et al. 2009, Frydman and
Jenker, 2010). This issue is beyond the scope of the current chapter but is left for future
research, building on recent OECD work on top incomes (Ruiz and Woloszko, 2015).
* An alternative method, when focusing on the business sector and working at the industry level, is to impute
the hourly compensation of a proprietor’s labour share by using the industry average compensation of
employees.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
101
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0104.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
National accounts data suggest a relative stability in the labour share over the last two
decades, on average across OECD countries for which the data are available (Figure 3.7),
somewhat in contrast with earlier studies. However, this average picture masks cross-
country heterogeneity. Slightly half of the countries experienced a decline in the labour
share: by more than 6 percentage points in Portugal, around 3 in the United States and 2
percentage points in Germany and Spain. Increases in the labour share experienced by the
other half of the countries were of lower magnitude, generally between 1 and 2 percentage
points, except in New Zealand and Sweden where such increases reached almost 5
percentage points.
The difference between the findings of this chapter and of previous studies is likely to
reflect differences in the vintage of the data and the nature of the approach. In particular,
most studies have measured the labour share for a subset of industries as opposed to the
Figure 3.7.
The labour share of GDP
1
Nominal terms
A. Labour income as a percentage of GDP
70
65
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
SVK CZE ITA PRT IRL HUN NZL ESP SWE KOR AUT FIN NLD DEU DNK GBR JPN USA FRA BEL SVN CHE
2013
1995
2007
70
65
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
B. Changes in the ratio of labour income to GDP, percentage points, 1995-2013
6
4
2
0
Average
-2
-4
-6
-8
PRT SVN JPN AUT USA ESP DEU KOR NLD CHE GBR SVK HUN DNK BEL
ITA
FIN
IRL FRA CZE SWE NZL
-2
-4
-6
-8
6
4
2
0
1. The labour share is defined as the sum of employees’ wages and compensation and labour income of the self-employed, over GDP.
Labour income of the self-employed is imputed by assuming that their annual wage is the same as for the average employee of the
whole economy. GDP and wages and compensation are expressed in current prices. For 1995, data refer to 1998 for the United States;
1999 for Spain, the United Kingdom, Hungary, Ireland and New Zealand. For 2013, data refer to 2014 for Czech Republic, Finland, Italy,
Korea, the Netherlands, Portugal, Sweden; 2012 for Switzerland, New Zealand and the United States.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324049
102
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0105.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
aggregate economy, for instance by focusing on the non-primary business sector (as done
in OECD, 2012) while others have also excluded the self-employed (as done in
Karabarbounis and Neiman, 2014). The current findings may mask compositional effects
arising from cross-industry differences as well as workers’ reallocation between industries.
As a result, the aggregate approach needs to be complemented with a finer industry-level
approach in future work.
The household capital income share of GDP
Capital represents a smaller source of overall income than labour for the average
household, but this this income source is far from negligible and highly variable across
countries (Figure 3.2).
19
Since capital is ultimately held by households, developments in
economy-wide capital income over the last decades should have ultimately trickled down
to the household sector.
20
This section provides a preliminary exploration of developments
in capital income for the average household with a view to shedding light on this issue.
Before doing so, it is useful to remind the SNA definition of household capital income. Such
income covers the three following items:
Household operating surplus:
this item corresponds to income from housing services, that
is, actual and “imputed” rents. In countries where homeownership is dominant such as
France and Italy, most output in the housing sector is recorded as imputed rent paid by
homeowners to themselves and this item amounts to around 10% of household adjusted
disposable income per capita.
Capital income of the self-employed:
this item corresponds to the remuneration of capital for
unincorporated enterprises, which are included in the household sector alongside “real”
households. The national accounts do not generally allow for distinguishing between
income from capital and labour for the self-employed, and the sum of the two is
therefore called “mixed income”. The split between the remuneration of labour and that
of capital needs to be imputed, as explained in Box 3.3. The resulting capital income
share is highly heterogeneous across countries, between 2.5% and 20% of adjusted
household disposable income per capita, not least reflecting the heterogeneous
incidence of self-employment.
Property income:
this item corresponds to the returns on households’ financial
investments (interest, dividends, and imputed interests from life insurance policies). It
represents a smaller part of household income per capita compared to other capital
income components and may not deliver a comprehensive assessment of returns to
financial capital, reflecting the following limitations: i) it excludes capital gains and
losses, whether realised or unrealised, and ii) as a result, it excludes capital gains from
share buy-backs, yet such corporate profits redistribution mechanism to shareholders
has been on the rise relative to dividend pay-out and iii) in some countries such as
Germany and Italy it includes self-employment income accruing to a very substantial
group of small individual firms.
21
The latter limitation has been shown to affect foremost
cross-country level comparisons, leaving trend comparisons largely unaffected.
22
Proper measurement of the capital income share ideally requires taking into account
capital depreciation. The increasing share of fast-depreciating capital, notably intangible
and knowledge-based capital (KBC) in all OECD countries implies an increase in the
average depreciation rate of the overall capital stock (Andrews and Criuscolo, 2013). Experts
generally assume a depreciation rate around 15% for intangible capital, which is much
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
103
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0106.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
higher than the depreciation rate applied to tangible capital, although this is a new area of
research which implies that any such estimate is surrounded by uncertainty. Even without
formally taking into account KBC, recent empirical findings based on a sample of G7
countries suggest that trend rise in the capital income share is less pronounced when
measured in net terms, reflecting increasing depreciation rates (Rognlie, 2015).
In practice however, methods for calculating consumption of fixed capital are complex
and tend to differ between countries, thus creating doubts about the comparability of
results. In addition, depreciation data are only available for a subset of countries in the
SNA. As a result of these issues, this chapter presents both gross and net capital income
shares. While the net concept is more appropriate in theory, results should be interpreted
with care, reflecting comparability and measurement issues.
According to SNA data, the household capital income share of GDP (i.e. the ratio of
capital income accruing to the household sector over GDP) has declined in the vast
majority of OECD countries since the mid-90s (Figure 3.8).
23
The average decline of 2.5
percentage points masks cross-country differences in magnitude: from more than 12
percentage points in Italy to around 1 percentage point in France. The decline in property
income may partly reflect declining interest payments on government debt held by
households, as suggested by the sharper decline observed in Italy and Belgium, since in
these countries bonds and other debt securities represent a higher proportion of household
financial assets compared to the rest of the OECD.
24
Portugal and the United States are
among the few countries experiencing a rise in the household capital income share and
they are also among the countries experiencing a marked decline in the labour share. This
Figure 3.8.
The evolution of the household capital income share of GDP and its components
1
Nominal terms, percentage points, 1995-2013
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
ITA
Household operating surplus
Gross household capital income, total
Property income
Net household capital income
Capital income of the self-employed
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
Average (gross household capital income)
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
BEL HUN CZE
IRL
NLD GBR DNK CHE SVN AUT ESP FRA
JPN DEU
FIN
SWE USA PRT SVK
-14
1. The household capital income share is defined as the sum of household operating surplus, capital income of the self-employed and
property income, over GDP. Capital income of the self-employed is imputed by the difference between their mixed income and their
labour income, assuming that their annual wage is the same as for the average employee of the whole economy. GDP and household
capital income are expressed in current prices. Net capital income is obtained by subtracting households’ consumption of fixed
capital from gross capital income. For 1995, data refer to 1998 for the United States; 1999 for Spain, the United Kingdom, Hungary,
Ireland and New Zealand. For 2013, data refer to 2014 for Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the Netherlands, Portugal, Sweden;
2012 for Switzerland, New Zealand and the United States.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324054
104
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0107.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
could suggest a shift in the functional income distribution. Nevertheless, a number of
countries experienced a decline in the household capital income share amid stability
(e.g. United Kingdom) or decline (e.g. Austria) in the labour share.
Income from housing services has been the only component of household capital
income not falling relative to GDP. This corresponds to rental income, most of which is
imputed in the national accounts on the grounds of owner-occupied housing. This finding
echoes recent work by Rognlie (2015) as well as Bonnet et al. (2014) who show that the trend
rise in the capital share of GDP has been driven by the housing sector.
25
This could mitigate
the adverse distributional consequences of rising capital incomes, because housing is
more equitably distribut ed than other capital assets (i.e. financial assets), as recently
shown in OECD (2015b).
26
The role of housing cannot be properly addressed through SNA
data, due to cross-country differences in the methodology applied for imputing owner-
occupied rents (Box 3.1).
Parallel declines in labour and household capital income shares of GDP could suggest
that a rising share of primary income has been retained by the corporate sector. This would
be consistent with Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014) who show that the decline of the
labour share has been the counterpart of a concomitant increase in corporate savings.
27
Nevertheless, the findings reported in this chapter provide a more complex picture:
widespread declines in the household capital income share have coincided with mixed
developments in the labour share (i.e. increases in some countries, declines in others). The
decline in household capital income could nevertheless be overestimated in the current
analysis if the nature of capital income has been changing towards forms of remuneration
that are not covered by the SNA. This notably applies to realised capital gains, as discussed
before, including share buy-backs, which have been increasingly used by corporations as a
way to redistribute profits to shareholders. Assessing developments in household capital
income in association with developments in corporate profit distribution and savings
behaviour is also an important area for future research.
The household secondary income share of GDP
Developments in the household income share of GDP may also reflect income flows
between the household and the government sector. Indeed, so far the analysis has focused
on household primary income, that is, income from labour and capital. This needs to be
complemented with an analysis of household secondary income, that is, income that the
government redistributes in cash or in-kind to households, net of the current taxes on
income and wealth paid by households (see Figures 3.1 and 3.2).
Secondary household income shares of GDP have been rising in many countries
(Figure 3.9, Panel A). This finding should be qualified: it largely reflects higher social
transfers and lower taxes during the crisis period (Figure 3.9, Panels B and C), which have
cushioned household disposable incomes from the falls in GDP and market income. Apart
from the crisis period, cross-country trends have been heterogeneous, with around one
third of countries experiencing declines of more than 2 percentage points, another third
facing rises of more than 2 percentage points, and the rest seeing relative stability in the
share of household secondary income in GDP (Figure 3.9). All in all, income redistributed by
the government does not appear as a major long-term driver of disposable income for the
average household, but rather as a key income stabiliser over the economic cycle, which is
broadly consistent with priors on the cushioning role of the welfare state.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
105
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0108.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.9.
The evolution of the household secondary income share of GDP
1
Nominal terms, percentage points, 1995-2013
A. 1995-2013
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
SWE AUT DEU FRA KOR DNK PRT CZE CHE HUN NLD BEL
FIN
SVN ESP
ITA
IRL
GBR SVK USA JPN
Average
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
B. 1995-2007
6
4
2
Average
0
-2
-4
-6
0
-2
-4
-6
6
4
2
SWE FIN
DNK ESP AUT CZE KOR GBR FRA HUN SVN BEL DEU PRT
IRL
CHE USA NLD
ITA
SVK JPN
C. 2007-13
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
DEU PRT NLD CHE FRA KOR AUT BEL SVK HUN
ITA
CZE SWE JPN SVN
IRL
DNK USA GBR
FIN
ESP
Average
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
1. The household secondary income share is defined as the sum of the net social benefits, transfers, and social transfers in-kind
received by households, minus current taxes on income, wealth, etc. over GDP. The household secondary income share is defined as
the ratio of household secondary income over GDP. GDP and household secondary income are expressed in current prices. For 1995,
data refer to 1998 for the United States; 1999 for Spain, the United Kingdom, Hungary, Ireland and New Zealand. For 2013, data refer
to 2014 for Czech Republic, Finland, Italy, Korea, the Netherlands, Portugal, Sweden; 2012 for Switzerland, New Zealand and the
United States.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324062
106
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0109.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
The finding of an increase in income redistributed from governments to households could
also be overestimated to the extent that consumption taxes are excluded from taxes paid by
households in the SNA framework, as emphasised above. Yet across high-income countries
the recent period has been characterised by a trend shift in the tax structure towards
consumption taxes,
28
which is likely to have reduced the purchasing power of household
incomes. Indeed, this is in line with the findings reported in the first section of this chapter,
that is, a decline in real household incomes, when nominal household income is deflated with
consumer prices, as those have increased in many countries relative to output prices.
A Wrap-up on the household income share of GDP
To wrap-up, the changes in the household income share of GDP presented at the
beginning of this chapter can be decomposed as changes in the labour share of GDP, in the
household capital income share of GDP, and in the household secondary income share of
GDP (Figure 3.10). This summary decomposition delivers the following broad conclusions:
Over the period 1995-2013, declines in the household income share of GDP were in most
cases largely driven by declines in the household capital income share of GDP while
increases were driven by increases in the household secondary income share of GDP. The
contribution of labour income was heterogeneous across countries, but generally of
lower magnitude (Figure 3.10, Panel A).
The relative contribution of labour, household capital and household secondary income
shares partly reflects the cushioning role of secondary income redistributed by
governments at the onset of the crisis (Figure 3.10, Panels B and C). Indeed, most
OECD countries experienced declines in the household income share of GDP over the
pre-crisis period; this was driven by declines in primary incomes, in particular by
declines in the household capital income share but also, though to a lesser extent, by
declines in the labour share. Such declines were not generally compensated by increases
in household secondary income shares of GDP, in contrast with the crisis period.
From functional income distribution to income inequality
Functional income distribution, which can be defined as the division of income
between labour and capital, is often expected to explain income inequality. However, the
link is not a simple one whereby income is divided into workers receiving only wages and
capitalists or landlords receiving only profits and rents. First, most people have multiple
sources of income, notably from labour and from capital; second, there is considerable
inequality within each category of income, notably within labour and capital income. Even
if there were only two types of income, wage and capital, the effect on income inequality
of changes in the functional income distribution would depend on the degree of correlation
between wage and capital income and on the relative dispersion between the two income
sources.
29
Market income
Empirically, declines in the labour share have been associated with widening market-
income inequalities,
30
even though the correlation is not very high and a number of
countries have experienced increases in both labour shares
and
inequality of market
incomes (Figure 3.11). The association is even weaker for household capital income.
Developments in the household capital income share reveal nothing on market-income
inequality, as most OECD countries have experienced declines in household capital income
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
107
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0110.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.10.
Decomposing the changes in the household income share of GDP
1
Nominal terms, percentage points
Labour share of GDP
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
Capital income share of GDP
Secondary income share of GDP
Household income share of GDP
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
A. 1995-2013
AUT
BEL
ITA
HUN PRT NLD CZE SVN DNK CHE DEU ESP FRA GBR
IRL
SWE JPN
FIN
USA SVK
B. 1995-2007
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
SVN
BEL DNK AUT CZE
FIN
ESP NLD SWE
ITA
HUN PRT DEU JPN CHE
IRL
GBR FRA USA SVK
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
C. 2007-13
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
AUT HUN
ITA
PRT CHE FRA DEU BEL
NLD CZE GBR SVK
IRL
USA SVN ESP
JPN DNK SWE
FIN
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
1. See Figures 3.7 to 3.9 for the definition of respectively the labour share, the household capital income share (gross terms), and the
household secondary income share. GDP and the various components are expressed in current prices. For 2013, data refer to 2014 for
Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal and Sweden; 2012 for New Zealand and Switzerland. For Chile and
Korea, the component “Operating surplus” includes mixed income. For panel C, 1999 instead of 1995 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain, the
United Kingdom and New Zealand and 1998 for the United States.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324070
108
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0111.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Figure 3.11.
Developments in the labour share and in market income inequality¹
Nominal terms, percentage points, 1995-2012
Change in the Gini coefficient for household market income
12
JPN
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
SVN
AUT
DEU
PRT
USA
KOR
CHE
SVK
NLD
ESP
GBR
IRL
FRA
DNK
ITA
12
Correlation coefficient = -0.36
10
8
6
CZE
FIN
SWE
4
2
0
BEL
NZL
-2
-4
-6
-8
3
4
5
Change in the labour share
1. See Figure 3.7 for a definition of the labour share. Inequality is measured by the Gini index coefficient for pre-tax and transfer income
(market income). The values of the Gini coefficient range between 0, in the case of “perfect equality” (i.e. each share of the population
gets the same share of income), and 1, in the case of “perfect inequality” (i.e. all income goes to the individual with the highest income).
For 1995, data refer to 1998 for the United States, 1999 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain, New Zealand and the United Kingdom. For 2012, data
refer to 2011 for Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Switzerland and Sweden.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts and Income Distribution Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933333811
shares and increases in inequality of market incomes (Figure 3.12). This is likely to reflect
measurement limitations associated with household capital income, such as the non-
recording of capital gains in national accounts. Measurement limitations also apply to Gini
coefficients. Generally computed on household surveys, they tend to under-estimate top
incomes and thus the dispersion of capital incomes.
Figure 3.12.
Developments in the household capital income share
and in market income inequality
1
Nominal terms, percentage points, 1995-2012
Change in the Gini coefficient for household market income
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-11
-10
-9
-8
-7
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
Change in the household capital income share
NLD
SVK
BEL
DNK
CHE
GBR
ITA
CZE
SVN
PRT
Correlation coefficient = 0.02
IRL
ESP
FRA
AUT
FIN
SWE
DEU
USA
JPN
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
1. See Figure 3.8 for a definition of the household capital income share and Figure 3.11 for the Gini index. For 1995, data refer to 1998 for
the United States, 1999 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain, New Zealand and the United Kingdom. For 2012, data refer to 2011 for Canada,
Denmark, France, Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Switzerland and Sweden.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts and Income Distribution Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933333824
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
109
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0112.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Secondary or redistribution income allows for moving from market income to
disposable income, i.e. market income net of current income taxes paid and transfers
received by households from the government. The association between developments in
the household secondary income share of GDP and in inequality of household disposable
income is negative and relatively strong (Figure 3.13, Panel A). Redistribution income is
indeed meant to reduce the impact of market income inequality on disposable income
inequality. Nevertheless, the redistributive effect of taxes and transfers is heterogeneous
across OECD countries: for a given rise in secondary income accruing to the average
household, countries are more (e.g. Portugal) or less (the Netherlands) successful at
moderating the transmission from market income inequality to disposable income
inequality (Figure 3.13, panel B).
Figure 3.13.
Developments in the household secondary income share and in income inequality
1
Nominal terms, percentage points, 1995-2012
A. Developments in the household secondary income share and
in disposable income inequality
Change in the Gini coefficient for household disposable income
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Change in the household secondary income share
AUT
CZE
CHE
SWE
FRA
FIN
DNK
ESP
GBR
SVN
HUN
BEL NLD
PRT
ITA
SVK
Correlation coefficient = -0.41
6
USA
JPN
4
2
0
IRL
-2
-4
-6
8
DEU
Change in the extent of redistribution
16
SWE
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
AUT
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
-3
-2
-1
0
B. Developments in the household secondary income share and
in the extent of redistribution
Correlation coefficient = -0.63
FIN
DNK
NLD
FRA
DEU
CZE
CHE
BEL
PRT
1
2
3
4
SVN GBR
ESP
ITA
IRL
JPN
5
6
7
8
9
Change in the household secondary income share
SVK
USA
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
1. See Figure 3.9 for a definition of household secondary income share and Figure 3.11 for the Gini index. The extent of redistribution is
defined as the difference between the Gini coefficients for disposable and market income, relative to the value of the Gini coefficient
for market income. It is measured in terms of the change over the period 1995- 2012. For 1995, data refer to 1998 for the United States,
1999 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain, New Zealand and the United Kingdom. For 2012, data refer to 2011 for Canada, Denmark, France,
Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Switzerland and Sweden.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts and Income Distribution Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933333836
110
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0113.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
A Wrap-up on income distribution
Wrapping-up on the different components of household income, i.e. labour, capital
and secondary income, changes in the overall household income share of GDP are
positively but weakly correlated with changes in disposable income inequality
(Figure 3.14). This would imply that as the household sector receives a larger share of GDP,
income dispersion across the household sector increases, a somewhat counter-intuitive
finding. This is more likely to reflect that income distribution between the household and
non-household sectors of the economy has little information value about income
distribution within the household sector, as it largely ignores the major drivers of
dispersion at the level of market incomes: inequality between workers and non-workers
and inequality among workers, as well as taxes and transfers as a major source of income
and a redistributive tool to mitigate market income inequality.
Figure 3.14.
Wrapping-up: developments in the household income share
and in disposable income inequality
1
Nominal terms, percentage points, 1995-2012
Change in the Gini coefficient
8
SWE
6
4
2
0
ITA
-2
BEL
-4
-6
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Change in the household income share
NLD
HUN
CHE
PRT
AUT
DNK
DEU
SVN
CZE
ESP
GBR
IRL
SVK
FRA
JPN
FIN
USA
Correlation coefficient = 0.21
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
1. Household income and Gross domestic product (GDP) are expressed in current prices. Inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient
for post-tax and transfer income (disposable income). See Figure 3.11 for a definition of the Gini index. For 1995, data refer to 1998 for
the United States, 1999 for Hungary, Ireland, Spain, New Zealand and the United Kingdom. For 2012, data refer to 2011 for Canada,
Denmark, France, Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Switzerland and Sweden.
Source:
OECD,
National Accounts and Income Distribution Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933333848
Notes
1. Stiglitz et al. (2009), Atkinson, (2012, 2015), OECD, (2008), (2011a), (2011b), (2015),
OECD Better Life
Initiative, OECD Inclusive Growth Initiative,
Piketty (2013), Causa et al. (2014a, 2014b).
2. See also Atkinson, (2012), OECD, (2011a),
OECD Better Life Initiative, OECD Inclusive Growth Initiative,
Causa et al. (2014a).
3. Empirical evidence on income distribution and on the influence of growth-oriented policies on
income distribution is relatively rich. See Causa et al. (2014a, 2014b), OECD, (2011b), Braconier and
Ruiz-Valenzuela (2014), Fournier and Koske, (2012), Joumard et al. (2012), Koske et al. (2012),
Jaumotte and Osorio Buitron (2015). This has allowed for progressively incorporating income
inequality among the objectives of policymaking, for instance among the policy recommendations
formulated in
Going for Growth
reports.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
111
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0114.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
4. This paper relies on a comprehensive use of the SNA and its guide (Lequiller and Blades, 2014). The
SNA defines six institutional sectors: households (S14); non-financial corporations (S11); financial
corporations (S12); general government (S13); non-profit institutions serving households (S15); and
the rest of the world (S2).
5. An estimate of income derived from the underground (or hidden) economy is included in the SNA
and represents a large share of GDP in many countries (for example around 11% in Spain). See
Lequiller and Blades (2014). Household income in the SNA consistently includes income derived
from hidden activities. The majority of hidden activities are related to small enterprises. As a
consequence, the main part of the adjustment ends up in output and value added of households
(for example in self-employment income).
6. See Atkinson (2009) and (2012) for a discussion and the definition of “spendable income”.
7. Consumption of fixed capital is defined as the reduction in the value of the fixed assets used in
production. At the household level, the most important fixed asset is usually housing. Under the
SNA framework, consumption of fixed capital is estimated by applying a depreciation rate to the
current value of each capital asset,
i.e.
its current market price. The depreciation rate varies across
countries and depends on the assumption about assets’ service lives (i.e., how long the asset is
assumed to be used; for example in the United States it is assumed that the service life of a
dwelling is 80 years). Depreciation functions may be geometric (US assumption for dwellings) or
linear. On average across OECD countries for which data are available, consumption of fixed capital
represents 5% of net adjusted household disposable income.
8. There are well-known measurement issues in the estimation of households’ consumption of fixed
capital, suggesting that gross adjusted disposable income may be more appropriate for cross-
country comparison purposes. The correlation between them is close to one (0.99).
9. Self – employment income corresponds to the SNA item “mixed income”: so-called because this
category includes both the remuneration of labour and that of capital.
10. This pattern is in line with recent OECD work on inequality trends during the crisis, where it is
shown that taxes and social transfers alleviated the effects on disposable incomes of falling
market incomes during the crisis (OECD, 2013c).
11. Many OECD countries have been raising their standard VAT rate, in particular between 2009
and 2014. The OECD average standard VAT rate reached 19.1% in January 2014, from 17.6% in January
2009. Ten OECD countries now have a standard rate above 22% versus four in 2009. See OECD (2014).
12. For example, household income includes -- while GDP excludes -- the wages and salaries of
workers who are resident in a country but working in neighbouring countries; conversely,
household income excludes, while GDP includes, the wages and salaries of workers who are
non-resident of a country where they have come to work.
13. GNI is not affected by the activity of multinationals and therefore the allocation of value added and
profits across countries. In the SNA, all profits end up in the country of residence of the
multinational, via the item “reinvested earnings on foreign direct investment” in the business
accounts: see Chapter 7 in Lequiller and Blades, (2014).
14. The same diagnosis applies to the household income share of GNI (not shown).
15. This finding confirms earlier results by Causa et al. (2014b).
16. See Causa et al. (2014b) for a discussion.
17. For instance companies may defer cash dividends distribution because the cyclical or institutional
context makes it more attractive to accumulate cash or retain earnings for investment purposes.
The part of household capital income that accrues in the form of capital gains is
de facto
excluded
from the SNA.
18. See OECD, (2012) for a recent in-depth assessment and policy analysis., see also
inter alia
Arpaia
et al. (2009); Azmat et al. (2012), Bentolila and Saint-Paul (2003), Checchi and Garcia-Penalosa,
(2008, 2010), De Serres at al. (2002), Elsby et al. (2013), European Commission, (2007), Frydman and
Saks, (2010), Harrison, (2002), Jaumotte and Tytell, (2007); more recent papers have analysed the
concomitant rise in the capital share: see Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014), Piketty (2013), Piketty
and Zucman (2014), Rognlie (2015).
19. Trend rises in the aggregate capital share of GDP among high-income countries since the post war
area have been documented and received growing attention among researchers and policymakers,
not least reflecting associated inequality implications (Piketty, 2013). See Karabarbounis and
Neiman (2014), Piketty (2013), Piketty and Zucman (2014), Rognlie (2015). The most recent period is
112
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0115.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
however characterized by a marked decline in the investment rate hence in capital per worker as
discussed for instance in Chapter 3 of OECD (2015a). The impact on the functional income
distribution is likely to depend on number of factors such as substitutability between capital and
labour. The impact on the household capital income share is likely to materialize with a lag and
will depend on companies’ profits and their redistribution strategies.
20. Capital income of general government is null by construction, because the output of the general
government sector consists of non-market output and is valued “at cost”, meaning that value
added is equal to labour costs (i.e. compensation of civil servants, which is included in the
aggregate labour share).
21. In Italy, unincorporated enterprises with more than five employees are considered as “quasi-
corporations” and are therefore classified in the corporate sector. This implies an overestimation
of the profit share hence an underestimation of the labour share. See Guidetti and Pionnier, (2015)
for a detailed assessment.
22. This conclusion is based on findings reported in Guidetti and Pionnier (2015).
23. These results pre-date the crisis: similar conclusions are reached for the period 1995-2013.
24. OECD (2015b), Chapter 6.
25. The finding of positive effects from housing assets is also emphasized in recent OECD work on
household wealth: OECD (2015b) shows that rising house prices have been a key factor leading to
higher household wealth in some OECD countries such as Australia, Belgium, Canada, Spain and
the UK. In the SNA, the household income account does not allow for directly capturing capital
gains associated with rising house prices – unless indirectly reflected in rising actual and imputed
rents.
26. This argument remains tentative since the National Accounts data do not cover the income
distribution. See OECD (2015b), Chapter 6 for a recent focus on household wealth and its
distribution.
27. The authors develop a model-based explanation for these trends: that is, a global decline in the
cost of capital, which has induced firms to shift away from labour and towards capital, financed in
part by an increase in corporate savings.
28. OECD (2014).
29. The higher the dispersion of capital relative to labour income and the higher the correlation
between the two income sources, the most likely will the decline in labour share result in higher
inequality.
30. See OECD (2012), Checchi and Garcia Penalosa (2008, 2010).
Bibliography
Andrews, D. and C. Criscuolo (2013), “Knowledge-Based Capital, Innovation and Resource
Allocation”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers
1046, OECD Publishing Paris,
http://
dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k46bh92lr35-en.
Arpaia, A., E. Prez and K. Pichelmann (2009), “Understanding Labour Income Share Dynamics in
Europe”,
European Economy Economic Papers
No. 379, European Commission, Brussels, May.
Atkinson, A.B, T. Piketty, and E. Saez, (2011), “Top incomes in the long run of history”,
Journal of Economic
Literature,
American Economic Association, Vol. 49(1), pages 3-71, March.
Atkinson, A.B. (2009), “Factor shares: the principle problem of political economy?”
Oxford Review of
economic policy,
Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 3-16.
Atkinson, A.B. (2012), “Putting people first and macro-economic policy”, paper prepared for the OECD
New Approaches to Economic Challenges Group Meeting, October 2012.
Atkinson, A.B. (2015),
Inequality: what can be done?
Harvard University Press.
Azmat, G., A. Manning and J. van Reenen (2012), “Privatization and the decline of labour’s share:
international evidence from network industries”,
Economica,
Vol. 79 Issue 315, pp. 470-492.
Bassanini, A. and T. Manfredi (2012), “Capital’s Grabbing Hand? A Cross-country/Cross-industry
Analysis of the Decline of the Labour Share”,
OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
113
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0116.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Bentolila, S. and G. Saint-Paul (2003), “Explaining Movements in the Labor Share”,
Contributions to
Macroeconomics,
Vol. 3, No. 1.
Blanchard, O. and F. Giavazzi (2003), “Macroeconomic effects of regulation and deregulation in goods
and labor markets”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 115, pp. 879-907.
Bonnet, O., P.H. Bono, G. Chapelle and E. Wasmer (2014), “Does housing capital contribute to
inequality”? A comment on Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the 21st Century”,
Sciences Po Economics
Discussion papers 2014-07.
Causa, O. , A. Cavaciuti, N. Ruiz and Z. Smidova, (2014a) “GDP and Income Distribution Developments
Across OECD Countries”,
OECD Economics Department Working Paper,
No. 111, OECD Publishing Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jz5m89dh0nt-en.
Causa, O., A. De Serres and N. Ruiz (2014b) “Can Pro-growth policies lift all boats? An analysis based on
household disposable income”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers
No. 1180, OECD
Publishing Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jxrh8dh5wg7-en.
Checchi, D. and C. Garcia-Peñalosa (2008), “Labour Market Institutions and Income Inequality”,
Economic Policy,
Vol. 23, No. 56, pp. 601-649.
Checchi, D. and C. Garcia-Peñalosa (2010), “Labour Market Institutions and the Personal Distribution of
Income in the OECD”,
Economica,
Vol. 77, No. 307, pp. 413-450.
Corrado, C. , J. Haskel, Jona-Lasinio, C. and M. Iommi (2012), “Intangible Capital and Growth in
Advanced Economies: Measurement Methods and Comparative Results”, Intan Invest.
Dew-Becker, I. and R. J. Gordon (2005), “Where did the productivity go? Inflation dynamics and the
distribution of income”,
NBER Working Paper
11842.
Elsby, M. W, Honijin, B. and A. Sahin (2013), “The decline of the US labour share”,
Brookings papers on
Economic Activity,
Fall 2013, p. 51-63.
European Commission (2007),” The Labour income Share the European Union,” Chapter 5 of
Employment in Europe 2007,
Directorate-General for Employment, Social Affairs and Equal
Opportunities, Brussels.
Fernandes, N., M.A. Ferreira, P. Matos and K.J. Jenter (2009), “The pay divide: (why) are us top executives
paid more?”,
ECGI Working Paper
No. 255/2009.
Fournier, J.-M. and I. Koske (2013), “The Determinants Of Earnings Inequality: Evidence from Quantile
Regressions”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2012/1,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-
2012-5k8zs3twbrd8
Frydman, C. and D. Jenter (2010), “CEO Compensation”,
Annual Review of Financial Economics,
Vol. 2,
No. 1, pp. 75-102.
Giovannoni, O. (2014) “What do we know about the labor share and the profit share? Part III: measures
and structural factors”,
Economics Working Paper Archive
wp_805, Levy Economics Institute.
Guidetti and Pionnier (2015), “Comparing profit shares in value-added in four OECD countries: towards
more harmonised National Accounts”,
OECD Statistics Directorate Working Paper
No.61, OECD
Publishing, Paris.
Harrison, A. (2002), “Has globalization eroded labor’s share? Some cross-country evidence”, Paper
presented at the Joint Conference of the IDB and the World Bank: The FDI Race: Who Gets the
Prize? Is it Worth the Effort? October.
ILO (2012),
Global Wage Report 2012/2013: Wages and equitable growth,
Geneva.
Jaumotte, F and C. Osorio Buitron (2015), “Inequality and labour market institutions”,
IMF Staff
Discussion note SDN/15/14.
Jaumotte, F. and I. Tytell (2007), “How has the globalization of labor affected the labor income share in
advanced countries?”,
IMF Working Paper,
No. 07/298.
Joumard, I. , M. Pisu and D. Bloch (2012), “Tackling income inequality: the role of taxes and transfers”,
OECD Journal: Economic Studies,
Vol. 2012.
Karabarbounis, L. and B. Neiman (2014), “The global decline of the labour share”,
The Quarterly Journal
of Economics
129 (1), p. 61, 103.
Koh, D., R. Santaeulalia-Llopis, and Y. Zheng (2015), “Labour share decline and the capitalization of
intellectual property products”,
Washington University in Saint-Louis Working Paper
114
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0117.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
Koske, I., J. Fournier and I. Wanner (2012), “Less Income Inequality and More Growth – Are They
Compatible? Part 2. The Distribution of Labour Income”, OECD Economics Department Working
Papers, No. 925, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k9h2975rhhf-en
Lequiller, F. and D. Blades (2014),
Understanding national accounts:
Second Edition, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2008),
Growing Unequal? Income distribution and poverty in OECD countries,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264044197-en.
OECD (2011a),
How’s Life? Measuring well-being,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
9789264121164-en.
OECD (2011b),
Divided we stand: why inequality keeps rising,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/
10.1787/9789264119536-en
OECD (2012), “Labour losing to capital: what explains the declining labour share?”, Chapter 2 of
Employment Outlook 2012,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/empl_outlook-2012-4-en.
OECD (2014),
Consumption Tax Trends 2014: VAT/GST and excise rates, trends and policy issues,
OECD
Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/ctt-2014-en.
OECD (2015a),
OECD Economic Outlook Volume 2015/1,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
eco_outlook-v2015-1-en.
OECD (2015b),
In it together: why less inequality benefits all,
OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/
10.1787/9789264235120-en.
Piketty, T. (2013),
Le capital au XXIème siècle,
ed. Seuil, Paris.
Piketty, T. and G. Zucman (2014), “Wealth and inheritance in the long-run”,
CEPR discussion paper
No.DP10072.
Rognlie, M. (2015) “Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share”,
Brooking Chapters on Economic
Activity,
BPEA Conference Draft, March 19-20, 2015.
Ruiz, N. and N. Woloszo (2016), “What Do Household Surveys Suggest about the Top 1% incomes and
Inequality in OECD Countries?”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 1265,
http://
dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrs556f36zt-en.
De Serres, A., Scarpetta, S. and C. de la Maisonneuve (2002), “Sectoral shifts in Europe and the
United States: how they affect aggregate labour shares and the properties of wage equations”,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers
No 326, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/
763626062738
Stiglitz, J.E., A. Sen and J.-P. Fitoussi (2009),
Report by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic
Performance and Social Progress, www.stiglitzsenfitoussi.fr/documents/rapport_anglais.pdf.
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
115
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0118.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
APPENDIX 3.1
Policy drivers of the labour share: a brief literature
overview
Declines in the labour share have been documented over the past decades, even
though the magnitude of such a decline has been the object of controversies.
1
A wide array
of research has investigated the drivers of this trend, focusing in particular on the role of
globalisation along with that of changing policies and institutions. The main conclusions
from this literature can be summarised as follows:
Empirical evidence has pointed to negative effects of technical change and skill-biased
technical change embodied in ICT capital on the labour share, reflecting extensive
automation of production and substitution between capital and labour.
2
Technical change is becoming disembodied to the extent that it reflects the
accumulation of knowledge-based capital (KBC, including output from R&D, better
management, etc.). This also favours high-skilled workers, for instance because the
accumulation of KBC reflects productive improvements associated with highly-
qualified personnel.
However, disembodied technical change and the rising share of KBC have uncertain
effects on the aggregate labour share. First, in net as opposed to gross terms, the
process is not necessarily capital-augmenting once the higher depreciation rates for
KBC are accounted for; second, the process is likely to exacerbate wage inequality
between low- and high-skilled workers, reducing the labour share of the low-skilled
relative to that of the high-skilled, with ambiguous aggregate effects.
3
Evidence on the effect of globalisation on the labour share is not clear cut. Foreign
competition may reduce the bargaining power of workers in exposed industries, which
would not nevertheless necessarily imply a decline in the aggregate labour share. This is
likely to reflect the aggregate interplay between multiple confounding channels and
factors, such as differences in trade-induced reallocation between high and low-labour
share industries and differential effects between high and low-skilled workers.
4
Robust
findings for advanced countries can be summarised as follows (OECD, 2012, Bassanini
and Manfredi, 2012):
Rising offshoring of intermediate stages of production tends to reduce the labour share.
Competition from foreign firms in domestic market induces structural changes that
have different effects on the aggregate labour share, that is: i) greater import
penetration prompts reallocation of resources away from affected industries and
towards either domestic industries or countries with lower labour costs; and ii) growth
116
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0119.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
of import penetration appears more important in industries that are typically
characterised by a high labour share. The resulting larger trade-induced reallocation
away from these industries contributes to reduce the aggregate labour share, although
available evidence points to a small effect.
5, 6
Evidence on product market liberalisation pertains to the network industries, as most
reforms have been taking place in these industries during the 1990s.
Privatisation of SOEs tends to reduce the labour share within liberalised industries and
as a result the aggregate labour share.
Reductions in barriers to entry have no significant effect on the labour share. This is
likely to reflect the interplay between counter-balancing effects of pro-competitive
reforms: i) on the one hand, these reforms may erode firms’ rents and squeeze profits
hence increase the labour share;
7
ii) on the other hand, these reforms may erode the
bargaining power of the average worker hence reduce the labour share.
Available studies have been largely silent on reform-driven price effects and associated
effects on the labour share. Workers generally benefit from increased competition in the
form of gains in real wages. For example, trade liberalisation reforms that reduce
barriers to import competition should reduce consumption prices relative to GDP prices.
The descriptive analysis reported in this chapter suggests that relative price effects have
a large impact on real household developments. Proper identification of reform-driven
relative price developments is a challenging task for future research.
Empirical evidence on the effects of labour market policies on labour shares is mixed.
This probably reflects the differential effects across categories of workers, such as across
low and high-skilled workers (European Commission, 2007).
8
The main conclusions can
be summarised as follows:
Trends in the labour share cannot be strictly related to the nature of collective
bargaining or to its evolution (OECD, 2012).
9
This likely reflects the important and
confounding role of globalisation, increased competition and financial liberalisation,
which have: i) reduced the collective bargaining power of workers across the board,
that is, irrespective of wage bargaining regimes, and ii) at the same time, catalysed
wage bargaining reforms towards either more decentralisation or more centralisation
and co-ordination,
10
ultimately delivering wage moderation.
11
Increases in the statutory minimum wage relative to the median tend to reduce the
labour share, but the quantitative effect is estimated to be very small (OECD, 2012).
This could reflect that firms are induced to invest in labour-saving innovation
prompted by the need to contain the rise in labour costs. This finding would suggest
that large increases in minimum wage could reduce the labour share, even though
such increases might reduce wage inequality in the lower-half of the wage distribution
and in-work poverty. Indeed, empirical evidence based on European countries
suggests that higher minimum wages increase low-skilled labour shares and reduce
medium-skilled labour shares, resulting in a small negative effect at the aggregate
level (European Commission, 2007).
Stepping-up job search support and active labour market policies (ALMPs) while
reducing the generosity of unemployment benefits has been found to increase the
labour share of low-skilled workers across European countries (European
Commission, 2007). Well-designed and targeted activation and training policies
primarily induce an increase in employment of low-skilled workers, who are
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
117
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0120.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
overrepresented among the pool of unemployed. The evidence suggests that this
compensates any potential moderating effect on wages. The overall effect of higher
spending on ALMP on the aggregate labour share has been found insignificant,
reflecting a negative effect on the labour share of medium-skilled workers by contrast
to the effect on low-skilled workers; while that of higher UB replacement rates has
been found negative, reflecting a concomitant negative effect on the labour share of
low and medium-skilled workers.
Relaxing job protection has not been found to trigger any significant change in the
aggregate labour share, even though it has been found to boost aggregate productivity
growth. This neutrality may reflect the interplay of differential effects of job protection
between industries and workers. Empirical evidence based on European countries
suggests that stricter job protection increases high-skilled labour shares and reduces
medium-skilled labour shares, resulting in a small negative effect at the aggregate
level (European Commission, 2007). Non-standard employment has become the
predominant source of job creation in many OECD countries since the mid-nineties
(OECD, 2015, Chapter 4). More recent forms of non-standard employment such as on-
call work, subcontracted work and zero-hours contracts in e.g. the United Kingdom
and the United States certainly favour hiring flexibility for firms and in principle also
for workers who need it. However, in practice, for workers, they have been associated
with more wage variability and reduced firms’ obligations to ensure standard benefits
and protection; as well as with low career and training opportunities. Policy changes
of this type may reduce workers’ bargaining power and as a result, their wages,
especially for those with low skills.
The high growth of the financial sector has also been highlighted as a potential cause of
declining labour shares, even though direct empirical evidence is scarce.
12
The
deregulation of financial markets may have lowered workers’ bargaining power by
pressuring firms to reduce costs; hence to focus on core activities while sub-contracting
labour-intensive activities in order to reduce debt while at the same time generate high
short-term profits.
Notes
1. See OECD, (2012) for a recent in-depth assessment and policy analysis., see also
inter alia
Arpaia
et al. (2009); Azmat et al. (2012), Bentolila and Saint-Paul (2003), Checchi and Garcia-Penalosa,
(2008, 2010), De Serres at al. (2002), Elsby et al. (2013), European Commission, (2007), Frydman and
Saks, (2010), Harrison, (2002), Jaumotte and Tytell, (2007); more recent papers have analysed the
concomitant rise in the capital share: see Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014), Piketty (2013), Piketty
and Zucman (2014), Rognlie (2015).
2. Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014), Koh et al. (2015), OECD (2012), Arpaia et al. (2009), European
Commission (2007), Jaumotte and Tytell (2007).
3. This reflects differences in substitutability between capital and low skilled as opposed to high
skilled labour, because different degree of substitutability between capital and labour have
different implications on the effect on the labour share of a change in the relative price of labour.
When the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour is smaller than 1, the labour share
will increase if the capital-labour ratio increases. In this context, the price effect will dominate the
quantity effect. This implies that a reduction in workers’ bargaining power leading to a decline in
the real wage will reduce the labour share if the elasticity of substitution between labour and
capital is smaller than 1. Given that it is generally assumed that high skilled labour is
complementary to capital while low skilled labour is substitutable to capital, capital deepening can
increase the labour share of high skilled workers and reduce the labour share of low skilled
workers.
118
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0121.png
3. FROM GDP TO AVERAGE HOUSEHOLD INCOME: A LOOK AT THE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
4. See OECD (2012) for a discussion.
5. The finding of a small reallocation effect is in line with that of the documented negligible role of
reallocation in explaining changes in the aggregate labour share. See Bassanini and Manfredi
(2012).
6. European Commission (2007) finds a negative effect of openness on the labour share of medium-
skilled workers, and this drives a negative effect at the aggregate level.
7. This is the well-known prediction of a standard theoretical model with homogenous firms and
workers (Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2003).
8. Again, this is due to differences in the elasticity of substitution between capital and different types
of labour (e.g. low and high skilled). Reform effects are also likely to depend on the elasticity of
substitution in industries most affected by the reforms.
9. European Commission (2007) finds a negative effect of union density on the labour share of low-
skilled workers and a positive effect on the labour share of high-skilled workers. The authors
interpret this along the lines of complementarity between high-skilled work and capital and
substitutability between low-skilled work and capital. Union density is however a very crude and
partial measure which in isolation falls short of capturing the nature of wage bargaining.
10. Such pro-decentralisation reforms have largely aimed at increasing the flexibility to negotiate at
firm level. See OECD (2012) for an in-depth qualitative discussion of wage bargaining reforms.
11. See Box 3.5 in OECD (2012) for a summary of empirical studies on globalisation and increased
competition on workers’ bargaining power.
12. OECD (2012), ILO (2012).
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
119
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0123.png
Economic Policy Reforms 2016
Going for Growth Interim Report
© OECD 2016
Chapter 4
Structural policy indicators
This chapter contains a comprehensive set of quantitative indicators that allow for
a comparison of policy settings across countries. The indicators cover areas of
taxation and income support systems and how they affect work incentives, as well
as product and labour market regulations, education and training, trade and
investment rules and innovation policies. The indicators are presented in the form of
figures showing for all countries the most recent available observation and the
change relative to the previous observation.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli
authorities. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights,
East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
121
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0124.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.1.
Cost of labour
A. Minimum wages
1
As a percentage of median wage
2
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
JPN
ESP
SVN
MEX
GBR
USA
CZE
HUN
RUS
CAN
NLD
CHN
AUS
KOR
GRC
BRA
EST
FRA
TUR
LUX
IND
SVK
LVA
IDN
ISR
OECD
COL
TUR
PRT
POL
CHL
BEL
IRL
NZL
EU
0
2014
2009
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
B. Minimum cost of labour
3
As a percentage of labour cost of median worker
2
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
JPN
IRL
GBR
CZE
USA
CAN
KOR
NLD
ESP
GRC
SVK
EST
BEL
ISR
EU
OECD
HUN
SVN
FRA
AUS
LUX
PRT
CHL
POL
NZL
0
2014
2009
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Missing countries do not have a national statutory minimum wage except for Mexico. Data refer to 2004-05 and 2009-10 for India; 2013
for Colombia.
2. Exactly half of all workers have wages either below or above the median wage for the OECD countries. Percentage of minimum to
average wage for China, Indonesia, the Russian Federation and India.
3. The cost of labour is the sum of the wage level and the corresponding social security contribution paid by employers.
Source:
Panel A: OECD,
OECD Employment Outlook Database;
China Ministry of Human Resources and Social Security, National Bureau of
Statistics;
Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios); International Labour Organisation
(ILO)
Database on Conditions of Work and Employment Laws;
Ministry of Man Power and Transmigration of the Republic of Indonesia and Statistics
Indonesia (BPS); Russia Federal State Statistics Service and Rani, U., P. Belser, M. Oelz and S. Ranjbar (2013), “Minimum wage coverage and
compliance in developing countries”
International Labour Review,
Vol 152, No.3-4; Panel B: OECD,
OECD Employment Outlook
and
Taxing Wages
Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324086
122
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0125.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.2.
Net income replacement rates for unemployment
Net income when unemployed as a percentage of net income when working
1
A. Initial²
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
GRC
KOR
TUR
AUS
USA
NZL
EST
CHL
GBR
HUN
SVK
SWE
FRA
POL
OECD
ESP
AUT
ITA
EU
DEU
CZE
CAN
NOR
IRL
ISL
FIN
PRT
BEL
JPN
NLD
CHE
SVN
DNK
ISR
LUX
LVA
LVA
0
2013
2008
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
B. 60th month³
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
ITA
TUR
CHL
GRC
USA
HUN
PRT
ESP
SVK
KOR
EST
ISR
CAN
OECD
EU
POL
AUS
FRA
NZL
CZE
BEL
SVN
DEU
SWE
GBR
NOR
CHE
NLD
DNK
ISL
LUX
AUT
FIN
IRL
JPN
2013
2008
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Simple average of the net replacement rates for the following households situations: single with no child and with two children at 67%
and 100% AW, one-earner married couple with no child and with two children at 67% AW and 100% AW. After tax and including
unemployment and family benefits. Social assistance and other means-tested benefits are assumed to be available subject to relevant
income conditions. Housing costs are assumed equal to 20% of AW. The OECD average excludes Chile for 2008 and Mexico for 2008
and 2013. For Turkey, the average worker earnings (AW) value is not available. Calculations are based on average production worker
earnings (APW).
2. Initial phase of unemployment but following any waiting period. Any income taxes payable on unemployment benefits are
determined in relation to annualised benefit values (i.e. monthly values multiplied by 12) even if the maximum benefit duration is
shorter than 12 months.
3. After tax and including unemployment benefits, social assistance, family and housing benefits in the 60th month of benefit receipt.
Values for Italy and Turkey are equal to zero in 2008 and 2013.
Source:
OECD,
Tax-Benefit Models.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324097
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
123
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0126.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.3.
Average tax wedge on labour
1
As a percentage of total labour compensation
A. At 67% of average worker earnings, single person without children
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
NZL
ISR
MEX
KOR
CHE
IRL
AUS
GBR
CAN
ISL
USA
LUX
JPN
NLD
OECD
NOR
POL
PRT
GRC
TUR
DNK
ESP
EU
FIN
SVN
SVK
EST
CZE
SWE
ITA
AUT
DEU
FRA
HUN
BEL
IDN
ZAF
IND
BRA
CHN
LVA
IDN
IND
ZAF
BRA
LVA
CHN
0
2014
2009
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
B. At 100% of average worker earnings, couple with two children²
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
NZL
CHE
IRL
ISR
MEX
KOR
LUX
AUS
CAN
USA
GBR
ISL
JPN
OECD
SVN
NLD
DNK
POL
CZE
SVK
NOR
PRT
EU
EST
ESP
TUR
SWE
HUN
FIN
DEU
AUT
ITA
FRA
GRC
BEL
0
2014
2009
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Measured as the difference between total labour compensation paid by the employer and the net take-home pay of employees, as a
ratio of total labour compensation. It therefore includes both employer and employee social security contributions. For India, the data
cover manufacturing companies with 20 or more employees (which represent 5% of all companies in the sector); liability to health
insurance and Employee Provident Fund contributions in India are restricted to employees in firms that have 20 or more employees.
In China, a significant portion of workers are not covered by the social security system; hence their tax wedge is significantly lower
than the figure reported here, which reflects the situation of workers covered.
2. Couple with two children, at 100% of average worker earnings for the first earner. Average of three situations regarding the wage of
the second earner (0%, 33% and 67% of average worker earnings).
Source:
OECD,
Taxing Wages Database;
For BIICS countries, data represent the latest figures based on the methodology described in :
Gandullia, L., N. Iacobone and A. Thomas (2012), “Modelling the tax burden on labour income in Brazil, China, India, Indonesia and South
Africa”
OECD Taxation Working Papers,
No. 14; for Latvia, data are based on the methodology described in
Taxing Wages.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324108
124
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0127.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.4.
Marginal tax wedge on labour
1
As a percentage of total labour compensation for single persons without children
A. At 67% of average worker earnings
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
MEX
NZL
KOR
CHE
ISR
JPN
CAN
USA
POL
IRL
AUS
DNK
GBR
OECD
EST
ISL
NOR
TUR
SVN
SWE
ESP
LUX
SVK
NLD
GRC
CZE
EU
HUN
PRT
FIN
ITA
DEU
AUT
FRA
BEL
IDN
ZAF
CHN
IND
BRA
LVA
IND
IDN
ZAF
BRA
CHN
LVA
IND
IDN
ZAF
CHN
BRA
LVA
0
2014
2009
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
B. At 100% of average worker earnings
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
MEX
KOR
NZL
CHE
JPN
POL
ISR
AUS
GBR
CAN
EST
DNK
ISL
TUR
USA
OECD
SVK
SWE
CZE
GRC
HUN
ESP
NOR
SVN
NLD
EU
PRT
LUX
ITA
FIN
IRL
FRA
DEU
AUT
BEL
0
2014
2009
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
C. At 167% of average worker earnings
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
MEX
KOR
NZL
JPN
CHE
POL
CAN
ESP
AUS
EST
AUT
USA
DEU
SVK
ISR
OECD
TUR
ISL
CZE
HUN
GBR
EU
NOR
NLD
LUX
GRC
DNK
IRL
FIN
FRA
SVN
PRT
ITA
SWE
BEL
0
2014
2009
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Measured as the difference between the change in total labour compensation paid by employers and the change in the net take-home
pay of employees, as a result of an extra unit of national currency of labour income. The difference is expressed as a percentage of the
change in total labour compensation. For India, the data cover manufacturing companies with 20 or more employees (which represent
5% of all companies in the sector); liability to health insurance and Employee Provident Fund contributions in India are restricted to
employees in firms that have 20 or more employees. In China, a significant portion of workers are not covered by the social security
system; hence their tax wedge is significantly lower than the figure reported here, which reflects the situation of workers covered.
Source:
OECD,
Taxing Wages Database;
For BIICS countries, data represent the latest figures based on the methodology described in :
Gandullia, L., N. Iacobone and A. Thomas (2012), “Modelling the tax burden on labour income in Brazil, China, India, Indonesia and South
Africa”
OECD Taxation Working Papers,
No. 14; for Latvia, data are based on the methodology described in
Taxing Wages.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324113
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
125
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0128.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.5.
Changes in net pension wealth
1
As a percentage of gross annual individual earnings
A. Early retirement: age 55 to 59
15
2012
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
MEX
NZL
ESP
USA
DEU
GBR
PRT
NOR
DNK
CAN
FRA
ISL
BEL
EST
POL
CHL
NLD
AUS
SWE
IRL
JPN
OECD
FIN
SVK
KOR
AUT
EU
ISR
CZE
ITA
HUN
LUX
TUR
CHE
GRC
SVN
CHN
IDN
ZAF
BRA
LVA
RUS
IND
BRA
RUS
LVA
CHN
IDN
ZAF
IND
-20
2008
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
15
B. Old-age pension: age 60 to 64
15
2012
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
LUX
PRT
MEX
SVN
GRC
FRA
BEL
EST
DEU
USA
SWE
CAN
EU
NZL
ESP
AUS
GBR
OECD
DNK
NOR
HUN
AUT
POL
NLD
IRL
CHL
ISL
CHE
FIN
JPN
ISR
KOR
SVK
CZE
ITA
TUR
-20
2008
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
15
1. The change in pension wealth is a measure of the incentive to remain in the workforce for an additional period. It measures the
increase in the level of pension entitlement one gains by remaining in employment for an additional year. The calculation is the
annual average increase in males’ pension wealth when working from age 55 to 59 (early retirement) and from age 60 to 64 (old-age
pension). Net pension wealth is the present value of the flow of pension benefits, taking account of the taxes and social security
contributions that retirees have to pay on their pensions. It is measured and expressed as a multiple of gross annual individual
earnings in the respective country. See OECD (2013), Pensions at a Glance 2013: OECD and G20 Indicators for additional details.
Source:
OECD,
Pension Models.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324127
126
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0129.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.6.
Difference in net transfers to government: single and equal dual-earner couples
1
Percentage points
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
2013
2008
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
DEU
FRA
SVK
CZE
USA
HUN
EST
POL
ISL
CHE
DNK
CHL
BEL
JPN
SVN
OECD
TUR
EU
NOR
LUX
ESP
PRT
AUS
ITA
CAN
AUT
GBR
SWE
NZL
KOR
FIN
NLD
IRL²
GRC
MEX
1. The figure highlights the differential tax / benefit “regime” between single and dual-earner couple families, for a given overall level of
earnings – e.g. looking at couple families with incomes of 133% of average earnings. It shows the difference in net transfers to
government between two household cases: (1) “Single-earner couples” – with one earner with 133% of average earnings and (2) “Equal
dual-earner couples”- both spouses earn the same either average earnings or 67% of average earnings. The difference is in percentage
points and computed as [(1)-(2)]/(1).
2. The value for 2008 is not reported as it is highly distorted due to the fact that the net transfers to government from single-earner
couples is close to zero.
Source:
OECD,
Tax-Benefit Models.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324131
Figure 4.7.
Public expenditure on childcare services
1
As a percentage of GDP, 2011
2.25
Pre-school
2.00
1.75
1.50
1.25
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
SVK
JPN
SVN
ESP
LUX
GBR
DEU
HUN
KOR
NLD
FIN
NOR
EST
USA
CZE
AUS
MEX
DNK
ISR
PRT
AUT
CHL
POL
FRA
SWE
OECD²
LVA
BEL
ITA
IRL
NZL
EU²
ISL
0.00
Childcare
Total, 2006
LVA
2.25
2.00
1.75
1.50
1.25
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
1. Childcare expenditure covers children under three enrolled in childcare and children between the ages of three and five enrolled in
pre-school. Childcare refers to formal day-care services, such as day-care centres and family day-care. Pre-school includes
kindergartens and day-care centres which usually provide an educational content as well as traditional care for children (ISCED 0
under UNESCO’s classification system). Local government spending may not be properly captured in the data for federal countries.
2. EU and OECD averages exclude Canada, Greece, Switzerland and Turkey.
Source:
OECD,
Family and Social Expenditure Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324149
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
127
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0130.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.8.
Implicit tax on returning to work
1
As a percentage of gross earnings in new job, 2012
Childcare fee
Decrease in benefits
Increase in social contributions and income tax
Total increase
A. Second earner taking up employment²
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
ESP
NLD
HUN
DEU
JPN
SVK
FIN
DNK
CAN
SVN
CZE
LUX
ISR
BEL
AUS
CHE
USA
EST
FRA
PRT
AUT
POL
OECD³
KOR
GRC
SWE
NOR
GBR
LVA
LVA
ISL
IRL
NZL
EU³
-60
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
B. Lone parent taking up employment
4
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
HUN
NOR
GRC
KOR
NLD
SVK
ESP
GBR
DEU
EST
SWE
SVN
FRA
AUS
FIN
LUX
CZE
ISR
CHE
DNK
USA
CAN
PRT
POL
BEL
AUT
OECD³
JPN
NZL
ISL
EU³
IRL
-40
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
1. Net transfers and childcare fees for households with two children aged 2 and 3. Taking into account childcare fees and changes of
taxes and benefits in case of a transition to a job paying two-thirds of average worker earnings.
2. Second earner taking up employment at 67% of average wage and the first earner earns 100% of average wage.
3. The OECD average excludes Chile, Italy, Mexico and Turkey.
4. Lone parent taking up employment at 67% of average wage.
Source:
OECD,
Tax-Benefit Models; www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324153
128
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0131.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.9.
Net costs of childcare
Childcare-related costs and benefits as a percentage of average wage, 2012
Childcare fee
Childcare benefits
Tax reductions
Net Cost
A. Couples¹
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
NOR
GBR
HUN
KOR
SVN
NLD
ESP
SVK
LUX
GRC
DNK
CZE
CHE
DEU
SWE
CAN
USA
FRA
AUS
EST
JPN
AUT
PRT
POL
BEL
OECD²
NZL
LVA
LVA
ISR
FIN
ISL
EU²
IRL
-60
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
B. Lone parent¹
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
FIN
JPN
ISR
ISL
EU²
OECD²
NOR
NLD
ESP
GBR
DNK
HUN
CHE
SVN
EST
KOR
GRC
DEU
AUS
CAN
SVK
LUX
CZE
SWE
USA
FRA
PRT
AUT
POL
BEL
NZL
IRL
-80
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
-80
1. Couples where the first earner earns 100% of the average wage and the second earns 67% of the average wage. Lone parent earning
67% of the average wage. For Canada, the European Union, Finland, Norway, OECD, Slovak Republic, Slovenia and the United Kingdom,
childcare benefits refer to childcare and other benefits.
2. EU and OECD averages exclude Chile, Italy, Mexico and Turkey.
Source:
OECD,
Tax-Benefit Models; www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324163
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
129
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0132.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.10.
Average tax wedge: single parent versus second earner
Percentage
A. Single parent¹
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
IRL
NZL
CAN
AUS
ISR
CHE
GBR
LUX
CHL
DNK
NLD
USA
SVN
MEX
KOR
ISL
OECD
NOR
EU
JPN
CZE
PRT
HUN
SVK
ITA
EST
FIN
AUT
POL
ESP
DEU
SWE
TUR
BEL
FRA
GRC
IDN
ZAF
LVA
IND²
BRA
CHN
IDN
ZAF
IND²
BRA
CHN
LVA
-40
2014
2009
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
B. Second earner³
70
2014
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
ISR
MEX
KOR
CHE
GBR
NLD
JPN
NZL
NOR
IRL
USA
POL
TUR
AUS
OECD
FIN
GRC
CAN
LUX
SWE
ESP
EST
DNK
EU
SVK
AUT
PRT
ITA
ISL
FRA
CZE
HUN
SVN
DEU
BEL
0
2009
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
70
1. Single parent with two children earning 67% of the average wage.
2. Results apply only for the minority case where the employee works in a firm with more than 20 employees.
3. Average tax wedge faced by the second earner when earning 67 % of the average wage in a family with two children, where the first
earner receives a full average wage.
Source: Taxing Wages 2015 (calculations based on data retrieved from OECD.Stat: http://dotstat.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=AWCOU) and
Taxing Wages Models
for non-OECD member countries.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324177
130
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0133.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.11.
Number of weeks lost due to sick leave
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
SVK
ESP
NLD
GRC
GBR
SVN
TUR
NOR
USA
HUN
CHE
DNK
CZE
ITA
LUX
EST
CAN
AUT
POL
SWE
DEU
FRA
OECD¹
PRT
LVA
LVA
BEL
FIN
IRL
ISL
EU
0.0
2014
2009
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1. The OECD average excludes Australia, Chile, Israel, Japan, Korea, Mexico and New Zealand.
Source:
OECD estimates based on the European Labour Force Survey (unpublished data), the Canadian Labour Force Survey and published
U.S Current Population Survey estimates on lost working time rate due to injury or illness of full-time wage and salary workers.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324184
Figure 4.12.
Public expenditure on active labour market policies per unemployed
1
As a percentage of GDP per capita
1. Data refer to 2012 for France, Korea, New Zealand, Poland and Spain; 2011 for Israel and the United Kingdom. OECD and EU averages
exclude Greece, Iceland and Turkey.
Source:
OECD,
Public expenditure and participant stocks on Labour Market Programmes and Economic Outlook Databases.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324193
MEX
SVK
USA
CHL
ESP
EST
ISR
GBR
PRT
CAN
SVN
NZL
JPN
AUS
ITA
CZE
POL
IRL
OECD
EU
HUN
KOR
BEL
LUX
FRA
NLD
CHE
DEU
FIN
AUT
NOR
SWE
DNK
70
65
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2013¹
2008
70
65
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
131
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0134.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.13.
Employment protection legislation
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Protection for regular employment
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013¹
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
USA
CAN
GBR
NZL
HUN
CHE
IRL
AUS
JPN
EST
SVK
MEX
ESP
SVN
OECD
ISL
GRC
DNK
AUT
BEL
EU
POL
TUR
NOR
LUX
KOR
ISR
FIN
SWE
CHL
DEU
ITA
FRA
NLD
CZE
PRT
B. Protection for temporary employment
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013¹
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
CAN
USA
GBR
NZL
AUS
NLD
SWE
IRL
JPN
ISL
CHE
ISR
DEU
DNK
FIN
HUN
OECD
CZE
SVN
AUT
EU
MEX
POL
PRT
BEL
CHL
SVK
KOR
ITA
GRC
EST
ESP
NOR
FRA
LUX
TUR
C. Additional protection on collective dismissals²
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013¹
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
CHL
NZL
FIN
ISR
KOR
PRT
CZE
NOR
SWE
TUR
GBR
AUS
DNK
EST
POL
USA
OECD
CAN
EU
NLD
AUT
GRC
JPN
FRA
SVK
SVN
ESP
ISL
IRL
DEU
HUN
CHE
ITA
LUX
MEX
BEL
1. Data refer to 2014 for Colombia, Slovenia and the United Kingdom; 2012 for BRIICS countries and Latvia.
2. Values for 2013 are equal to zero for Chile, Indonesia and New Zealand.
Source:
OECD,
Employment Protection Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324200
132
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
IDN
IND
BRA
RUS
ZAF
CHN
LVA
COL
ZAF
RUS
LVA
CHN
COL
IND
IDN
BRA
COL
BRA
ZAF
LVA
RUS
CHN
IND
IDN
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0135.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.14.
Coverage rates of collective bargaining agreements and trade union density rates
Percentage
A. Coverage rates of collective bargaining agreements¹
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2013
2008
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
TUR
KOR
USA
MEX
POL
NZL
JPN
CHL
HUN
EST
SVK
ISR
CAN
GBR
IRL
GRC
CZE
CHE
OECD
DEU
LUX
AUS
EU
SVN
NOR
PRT
ESP
ITA
DNK
NLD
ISL
SWE
FIN
BEL
AUT
FRA
B. Trade union density rates²
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
EST
TUR
FRA
KOR
HUN
USA
CZE
POL
SVK
MEX
AUS
CHL
CHE
ESP
JPN
NLD
DEU
NZL
PRT
SVN
GRC
ISR
GBR
CAN
OECD
IRL
AUT
EU
LUX
ITA
NOR
BEL
DNK
SWE
FIN
ISL
IDN
LVA
BRA
RUS
ZAF
0
2013
2008
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. The coverage rate is measured as the percentage of workers who are covered by collective bargaining agreements, regardless of
whether or not they belong to a trade union. For 2013, data refer to 2012 for Australia, Estonia, France, Israel, Korea, Luxembourg,
Mexico, Poland, Indonesia and South Africa; 2011 for New Zealand; 2010 for Italy; 2009 for Ireland. For 2008, data refer to 2009 for Chile,
Denmark, Estonia, Hungary, Ireland, Mexico, Norway, Switzerland, Brazil, the Russian Federation and Latvia; 2007 for New Zealand,
Poland and Sweden; 2005 for Italy; 2000 for Israel.
2. The union density rate is the percentage of workers belonging to a trade union. The rates refer to wage and salary workers. The last
available year is 2014 for Australia, Canada, Chile, Iceland, Ireland, Japan, Mexico, New Zealand, Sweden, Switzerland, the
United Kingdom and the United States; 2012 for Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Latvia, Luxembourg, Poland, Portugal and South Africa; 2011
for Brazil.
Source:
OECD estimates and J. Visser,
ICTWSS Database, Version 5.0. Amsterdam: Amsterdam Institute for Advanced Labour Studies AIAS,
October 2015.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324219
IDN
LVA
RUS
ZAF
BRA
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
133
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0136.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.15.
Product market regulation and state control of business operation
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Restrictiveness of economy-wide product market regulation
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
NLD
ESP
EST
GBR
JPN
CAN
CHL
AUT
BEL
HUN
PRT
ITA
ISL
MEX
SVK
KOR
EU
OECD
DEU
LUX
SVN
GRC
DNK
CZE
NZL
ISR
FIN
AUS
IRL
FRA
NOR
SWE
TUR
CHE
POL
C. State control: involvement in business operation
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
NOR
AUS
CZE
DEU
SWE
GBR
DNK
AUT
NZL
IRL
FIN
EST
ISL
NLD
MEX
FRA
JPN
EU
CHE
CAN
OECD
SVK
ITA
HUN
POL
ESP
PRT
CHL
BEL
LUX
SVN
KOR
GRC
ISR
TUR
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324229
134
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
LVA
BRA
COL
ZAF
RUS
CHN
IND
LVA
COL
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CHN
IND
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
NLD
GBR
AUT
DNK
NZL
ITA
SVK
AUS
EST
FIN
DEU
PRT
HUN
EU
BEL
CZE
JPN
CAN
ESP
IRL
LUX
NOR
OECD
FRA
ISL
CHE
CHL
SWE
POL
SVN
GRC
KOR
MEX
ISR
TUR
B. State control: public ownership
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
LVA
COL
ZAF
RUS
BRA
CHN
IND
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0137.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.16.
Barriers to entrepreneurship
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Complexity of regulatory procedures
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
PRT
SVK
ITA
HUN
AUT
NLD
DNK
CAN
NZL
POL
LUX
MEX
BEL
FRA
FIN
EU
JPN
CHE
OECD
DEU
KOR
EST
NOR
GRC
AUS
SVN
GBR
CZE
ISL
SWE
ESP
IRL
ISR
TUR
CHL
B. Administrative burdens on startups
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
AUS
NZL
CHL
CHE
NLD
DNK
CAN
NOR
GBR
SWE
IRL
JPN
DEU
FIN
EST
KOR
OECD
SVN
EU
ISL
AUT
SVK
CZE
ITA
FRA
ISR
ESP
GRC
LUX
MEX
PRT
BEL
POL
HUN
TUR
C. Regulatory protection of incumbents
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
GBR
EST
CZE
AUT
SVK
SWE
POL
ITA
IRL
EU
SVN
ESP
PRT
CHL
DNK
NLD
FIN
GRC
FRA
OECD
LUX
NZL
BEL
DEU
CAN
HUN
CHE
ISL
JPN
NOR
KOR
TUR
AUS
ISR
MEX
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324232
LVA
COL
CHN
BRA
RUS
IND
ZAF
RUS
ZAF
COL
LVA
BRA
IND
CHN
RUS
COL
LVA
ZAF
CHN
BRA
IND
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
135
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0138.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.17.
Barriers to trade and investment
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Barriers to FDI
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
LUX
PRT
SVN
CZE
NLD
EST
FIN
ESP
DEU
HUN
GRC
DNK
EU
BEL
IRL
SVK
ITA
JPN
CHL
SWE
TUR
GBR
POL
OECD
CHE
NOR
FRA
AUT
AUS
KOR
ISL
ISR
CAN
MEX
NZL
COL
LVA
ZAF
BRA
RUS
IND
CHN
LVA
COL
RUS
ZAF
CHN
IND
BRA
IND
LVA
CHN
COL
ZAF
RUS
BRA
0.0
2013
2008
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
B. Tariff barriers
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
AUS
AUT
BEL
CAN
CHL
CZE
DNK
EST
FIN
FRA
DEU
GRC
HUN
ISL
IRL
ISR
ITA
JPN
LUX
NLD
NZL
NOR
POL
PRT
SVK
SVN
ESP
SWE
CHE
TUR
GBR
EU
OECD
MEX
KOR
0.0
2013
2008
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
C. Other barriers to trade and investment
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
AUS
NLD
NZL
GBR
BEL
POL
CHE
FIN
HUN
IRL
ISL
LUX
FRA
DEU
EU
ESP
CHL
PRT
ITA
OECD
CZE
DNK
AUT
NOR
GRC
KOR
SVK
SWE
JPN
EST
CAN
ISR
SVN
MEX
TUR
0.0
2013
2008
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324249
136
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0139.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.18.
Sectoral regulation in the transport sector
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Airlines sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
AUS
AUT
CHL
DEU
GRC
HUN
ISL
ITA
SVK
ESP
CHE
GBR
BEL
NLD
DNK
NOR
FRA
SWE
IRL
OECD
EU
CAN
JPN
KOR
ISR
LUX
FIN
MEX
NZL
TUR
POL
CZE
EST
PRT
SVN
B. Rail sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
GBR
CAN
CZE
DNK
DEU
AUS
AUT
EST
ITA
POL
NOR
JPN
SWE
HUN
NLD
SVK
EU
OECD
BEL
FRA
SVN
PRT
CHE
MEX
ESP
CHL
FIN
GRC
KOR
IRL
LUX
ISR
NZL
TUR
C. Road sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
AUS
CAN
ISR
CHE
AUT
DNK
FIN
DEU
IRL
JPN
LUX
MEX
NZL
NOR
SVK
SWE
GBR
OECD
HUN
EU
BEL
CZE
EST
ISL
KOR
NLD
POL
PRT
SVN
ESP
CHL
GRC
FRA
TUR
ITA
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324253
BRA
RUS
ZAF
IND
LVA
CHN
COL
LVA
RUS
COL
BRA
IND
CHN
ZAF
BRA
COL
IND
CHN
LVA
RUS
ZAF
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
137
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0140.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.19.
Sectoral regulation in the energy sector
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Electricity sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
ESP
PRT
DEU
GBR
CHL
ITA
HUN
FIN
AUT
BEL
NLD
EU
NZL
POL
JPN
SVK
IRL
AUS
NOR
SWE
CZE
OECD
DNK
CHE
SVN
GRC
LUX
TUR
FRA
EST
CAN
KOR
ISL
ISR
MEX
B. Gas sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
GBR
ESP
DEU
PRT
CAN
BEL
SWE
HUN
AUS
ITA
CZE
NZL
EST
AUT
CHL
EU
NLD
ISR
OECD
FRA
JPN
LUX
DNK
SVK
SVN
IRL
TUR
GRC
CHE
NOR
POL
FIN
MEX
KOR
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324263
138
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
COL
CHN
IND
RUS
LVA
ZAF
BRA
BRA
COL
RUS
IND
LVA
CHN
ZAF
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0141.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.20.
Sectoral regulation in the post and telecommunication sectors
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Telecommunication sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
GBR
POL
ITA
CZE
NLD
DNK
ISL
KOR
IRL
CAN
NZL
AUS
ESP
FIN
EST
HUN
PRT
GRC
EU
OECD
CHL
FRA
ISR
AUT
JPN
MEX
DEU
TUR
SWE
SVK
BEL
NOR
CHE
SVN
LUX
B. Post sector
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
NLD
DNK
BEL
DEU
AUT
CZE
POL
CHL
JPN
KOR
LUX
MEX
SVK
ESP
GBR
EU
OECD
SWE
CAN
FRA
IRL
GRC
EST
HUN
ISR
NZL
PRT
CHE
TUR
AUS
FIN
ITA
NOR
SVN
ISL
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324272
COL
RUS
LVA
BRA
CHN
IND
ZAF
BRA
COL
RUS
LVA
ZAF
CHN
IND
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
139
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0142.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.21.
Sectoral regulation in retail and professional services
Index scale of 0-6 from least to most restrictive
A. Retail
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
SWE
SVN
KOR
NZL
AUS
NLD
CHL
CHE
ISL
EST
IRL
CZE
DNK
SVK
GBR
PRT
NOR
OECD
HUN
MEX
EU
TUR
JPN
AUT
CAN
GRC
POL
FRA
DEU
FIN
ESP
ITA
ISR
BEL
LUX
B. Professional services
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2013
2008
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
SWE
FIN
GBR
DNK
CHE
AUS
NOR
NZL
NLD
IRL
MEX
CHL
ISL
EST
OECD
ITA
JPN
KOR
EU
FRA
CZE
ESP
BEL
SVN
ISR
DEU
AUT
SVK
PRT
GRC
HUN
CAN
POL
LUX
TUR
Source:
OECD,
Product Market Regulation Database
and Koske, I., I. Wanner, R. Bitetti and O. Barbiero, (2015), “The 2013 Update of the OECD
Product Market Regulation Indicators: Policy Insights for OECD and non-OECD Countries”, OECD
Economics Department Working Papers,
1200/2015; OECD-WBG
Product Market Regulation Database
for Colombia.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324281
140
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
COL
ZAF
BRA
CHN
LVA
ZAF
COL
BRA
IND
CHN
RUS
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0143.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.22.
Educational attainment
As a percentage of population aged 25-34 and 45-54, 2014
1
A. Upper secondary education
45-54
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
25-34
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
KOR
CZE
POL
SVN
CAN
SVK
CHE
ISR
FIN
IRL
AUT
USA
EST
DEU
HUN
LUX
AUS
GBR
FRA
NLD
EU
OECD²
BEL
DNK
SWE
GRC
NOR
NZL
CHL
ITA
ISL
ESP
PRT
TUR
MEX
B. Tertiary education
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
KOR
CAN
LUX
IRL
GBR
NOR
AUS
ISR
CHE
SWE
USA
NLD
BEL
FRA
POL
DNK
ESP
OECD
ISL
NZL
FIN
EST
EU
GRC
AUT
SVN
JPN
HUN
PRT
CZE
SVK
DEU
CHL
TUR
MEX
ITA
1. Data refer to 2013 for Brazil, Chile and France; 2012 for South Africa; 2011 for Indonesia; 2010 for China.
2. Data are missing for Japan.
Source:
OECD,
Education at a Glance 2015: OECD Indicators.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324290
LVA
COL
CHN
BRA
IDN
ZAF
LVA
ZAF
COL
BRA
IDN
CHN
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
141
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0144.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.23.
Graduation rates in upper secondary and tertiary education
1
Percentage
A. Upper secondary education
3
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2013
2005
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
NLD
SVK
GBR
EU
OECD
CHN
CHE
NOR
DEU
SWE
DNK
PRT²
RUS
TUR
SVN
ESP
CZE
FIN
IND
LUX
JPN
AUS
USA
CHL
AUT
NZL
LVA
ITA
0
2013
2005
MEX
TUR
ESP
LUX
CZE
ITA
SWE
USA
NOR
HUN
OECD
SVK
EU
SVN
CAN
CHL
POL
AUT
ISR
KOR
DNK
CHE
FIN
JPN
IRL
NZL
PRT²
GRC
ISL
B. Tertiary education
4
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Graduation rates represent the estimated percentage of people from a given age cohort that is expected to graduate at some point
during their lifetime. This estimate is based on the number of graduates in a given year, regardless of their age, divided by the size of
the average cohort of the typical age of graduation. In panel A, OECD and EU averages exclude Australia, Belgium, Estonia, France,
Germany, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom and exclude for 2005 only Austria, Hungary, Israel, Sweden, Switzerland and Turkey.
In panel B, OECD and EU averages exclude Belgium, Canada, Estonia, France, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Korea, Mexico
and Poland.
2. Estimated graduation rates can be very high, even above 100%, when a significant number of people above the typical age of
graduation returns to school. One such example is the New Opportunities programme in Portugal.
3. First-time graduation rates for ISCED 3. The last available year is 2014 for China and India; data refer to 2007-08 instead of 2005 for
India. For Brazil and the Russian Federation, data refer to graduation rate at upper secondary level for typical age from the general
programmes except for India for which upper secondary education is defined as persons aged 19 year olds who completed upper
secondary education.
4. First-time graduation rates for ISCED 5 to 7. Data refer to 2014 for China and India and to 2007-08 instead of 2005 for India. For India,
tertiary education refers to the 24 year olds and over who have graduated.
Source:
OECD,
Education at a Glance 2015: OECD Indicators;
CEIC for China data; India National Sample Survey.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324301
142
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
IND
RUS
CHN
BRA
IDN
COL
LVA
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0145.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.24.
Educational achievement
Average of PISA scores in reading, mathematics and science
1
550
2012
525
500
475
450
425
400
375
350
325
MEX
CHL
TUR
GRC
SVK
ISR
SWE
ISL
HUN
PRT
ITA
ESP
LUX
USA
NOR
OECD
DNK
SVN
FRA
EU
CZE
AUT
GBR
NZL
BEL
AUS
DEU
IRL
CHE
NLD
POL
CAN
EST
FIN
JPN
KOR
IDN
COL
BRA
RUS
LVA
IND
300
2009
550
525
500
475
450
425
400
375
350
325
300
1. PISA is the Programme for International Student Assessment. Data for India is the average for 2010 of the states of Tamil Nadu and
Himachal Pradesh and therefore may not be representative of nation-wide outcomes.
Source:
OECD (2014),
PISA 2012 Results: What Students Know and Can Do (Volume I, Revised edition, February 2014): Student Performance in
Mathematics, Reading and Science,
PISA.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324311
Figure 4.25.
Variance of educational achievement
Total variance in PISA scores in reading, mathematics and science
1
140
2012
130
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
2009
140
130
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
MEX
CHL
EST
TUR
DNK
IRL
POL
ESP
KOR
CAN
FIN
CZE
SVN
GRC
CHE
HUN
USA
PRT
AUT
NLD
OECD
EU
ITA
DEU
JPN
ISL
NOR
GBR
AUS
SWE
LUX
BEL
SVK
FRA
NZL
ISR
1. PISA is the Programme for International Student Assessment. OECD = 100. Average of PISA scores in mathematics and science only
in 2009 for France. The variance components in mathematics, sciences and reading were estimated for all students in participating
countries with data on socio-economic background and study programmes. The variance in student performance is calculated as the
square of the standard deviation of PISA scores in reading, mathematics and science for the sample of students used in the analysis.
Source:
OECD (2014),
PISA 2012 Results: What Students Know and Can Do (Volume I, Revised edition, February 2014): Student Performance in
Mathematics, Reading and Science,
PISA; OECD (2013),
PISA 2012 Results: Excellence through Equity (Volume II): Giving Every Student the Chance to
Succeed,
PISA.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324326
IDN
COL
BRA
LVA
RUS
50
50
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
143
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0146.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.26.
Influence of socio-economic and cultural background
on student reading performance
1
Strength of the link between the reading score and the socio-economic index
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
MEX
EST
TUR
ISL
CAN
ITA
CHL
ESP
PRT
KOR
NOR
FIN
USA
GRC
POL
LUX
DEU
OECD
CHE
JPN
SWE
NLD
DNK
IRL
EU
SVN
GBR
AUS
AUT
HUN
ISR
CZE
BEL
NZL
SVK
FRA
IDN
BRA
COL
LVA
RUS
COL
BRA
0
2012
2009
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1. Defined as the estimated coefficient from the country-specific regression of PISA reading performance on corresponding index of
economic, social and cultural status (ESCS).
Source:
OECD (2011),
Education at a Glance 2011: OECD Indicators;
OECD (2013),
PISA 2012 Results: Excellence through Equity (Volume II): Giving
Every Student the Chance to Succeed,
PISA.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324331
Figure 4.27.
Share of direct taxes
1
As a percentage of total tax revenue
80
2014²
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
CHL
MEX
TUR
ISR
HUN
GRC
GBR
NZL
KOR
EST
ISL
PRT
SVN
IRL
POL
OECD
EU
AUS
ITA
LUX
ESP
SVK
FIN
FRA
CZE
NLD
CAN
DNK
BEL
SWE
NOR
DEU
AUT
CHE
USA
JPN
0
2009
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1. Direct taxes aggregate taxes on income, profits and capital gains, social security contributions and taxes on payroll and workforce.
2. The last available year is 2013 for Australia, Brazil, Colombia, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands and Poland.
Source:
OECD,
Revenue Statistics Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324343
144
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0147.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.28.
Health expenditure
As a percentage of GDP
18
2013¹
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
TUR
EST
MEX
POL
LUX
KOR
CZE
CHL
HUN
ISR
SVK
IRL
GBR
SVN
FIN
ESP
ISL
AUS
EU
ITA
OECD
PRT
GRC
NOR
NZL
CAN
AUT
JPN
BEL
DNK
FRA
SWE
NLD
DEU
CHE
USA
IDN
IND
LVA
CHN
RUS
COL
ZAF
BRA
0
2008
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1. Data refer to 2014 for Canada, China, Finland, Germany, Iceland, Italy, Japan, Korea, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Slovenia and
Switzerland; 2012 for Australia, Ireland, Luxembourg.
Source:
OECD,
Health Database and China National Bureau of Statistics.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324352
Figure 4.29.
Producer support estimate to agriculture
As a percentage of farm receipts
70
65
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
NZL AUS CHL CAN ISR USA MEX OECD EU¹ TUR ISL JPN KOR CHE NOR
ZAF BRA RUS COL CHN IDN
2014
2009
70
65
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1. EU refers to all 28 members of the European Union.
Source:
OECD,
Producer and Consumer Support Estimates Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324368
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
145
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0148.png
4. STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.30.
Public investment
As a percentage of GDP
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
ISR
CHL
DEU
BEL
IRL
MEX
ITA
TUR
GBR
CHE
AUT
ISL
PRT
JPN
ESP
SVK
GRC
DNK
OECD
AUS
EU
NZL
NLD
FIN
USA
FRA
HUN
LUX
CAN
NOR
CZE
SWE
SVN
POL
KOR
EST
RUS
ZAF
COL
LVA
0.0
2009-14¹
2004-09²
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1. Average 2009-13 for Chile, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, the Russian Federation and Colombia.
2. Average 2006-09 for Turkey.
Source:
OECD,
Economic Outlook Database.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324378
146
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0149.png
4.
STRUCTURAL POLICY INDICATORS
Figure 4.31.
Financial support for private R&D investment
As a percentage of GDP
A. Direct public funding of business R&D
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
CHL
MEX
CHE
GRC
SVK
AUS
JPN
NLD
CAN
POL
TUR
PRT
LUX
ITA
DNK
NZL
IRL
FIN
OECD
NOR
DEU
ESP
EU
GBR
BEL
ISL
EST
FRA
SWE
ISR
CZE
HUN
KOR
USA
AUT
SVN
ZAF
CHN
RUS
RUS
BRA
ZAF
CHN
0.00
2011-13¹
2006-08²
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
B. Indirect public support through R&D tax incentives
3
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
2013
2006
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
1. Average of years 2011 and 2013 for Iceland, New Zealand and Sweden; average of years 2011 and 2012 for France, Ireland, Israel, Italy,
Portugal and South Africa; 2012 for Switzerland; 2011 for Australia, Austria, Belgium and Mexico; 2009 for Luxembourg.
2. Average of years 2006 and 2007 for Austria; average of years 2007 and 2008 for Chile and Denmark; 2007 for Greece, Luxembourg, the
Netherlands, New Zealand and Sweden; 2008 for Switzerland.
3. The last available year is 2012 for Belgium, Brazil, Ireland, Spain, Switzerland, the United States and South Africa; 2011 for Australia,
Iceland, Mexico and the Russian Federation. Instead of 2006, data refer to 2007 for Belgium, Denmark, Italy, Korea, Mexico, Slovenia and
Sweden; 2008 for Chile, New Zealand, Switzerland and Turkey; 2009 for China.
Source:
Panel A: OECD,
Science and Technology Indicators Database;
Panel B: OECD,
R&D Tax Incentives Database, www.oecd.org/sti/rd-tax-
stats.htm,
December 2015.
1 2
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888933324384
EST
DEU
MEX
NZL
SWE
CHE
SVK
ITA
CHL
FIN
ESP
TUR
GRC
NOR
CZE
DNK
ISL
USA
OECD
EU
GBR
PRT
SVN
AUT
AUS
HUN
JPN
NLD
IRL
CAN
BEL
KOR
FRA
ECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS 2016: GOING FOR GROWTH INTERIM REPORT © OECD 2016
147
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION
AND DEVELOPMENT
The OECD is a unique forum where governments work together to address the economic, social and
environmental challenges of globalisation. The OECD is also at the forefront of efforts to understand and
to help governments respond to new developments and concerns, such as corporate governance, the
information economy and the challenges of an ageing population. The Organisation provides a setting
where governments can compare policy experiences, seek answers to common problems, identify good
practice and work to co-ordinate domestic and international policies.
The OECD member countries are: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Chile, the Czech Republic,
Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea,
Luxembourg, Mexico, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, the Slovak Republic,
Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States. The European
Union takes part in the work of the OECD.
OECD Publishing disseminates widely the results of the Organisation’s statistics gathering and
research on economic, social and environmental issues, as well as the conventions, guidelines and
standards agreed by its members.
OECD PUBLISHING, 2, rue André-Pascal, 75775 PARIS CEDEX 16
(12 2016 01 1 P) ISBN 978-92-64-25007-9 – 2016
SAU, Alm.del - 2016-17 - Bilag 3: OECD publikationer om inklusiv vækst
1671173_0152.png
Economic Policy Reforms
Going for Growth
Interim Report
Going for Growth
is the OECD’s regular report on structural reforms in policy areas that have been identified
as priorities to boost incomes in OECD and selected non-OECD countries (Brazil, China, Colombia, India,
Indonesia, Latvia, Russian Federation and South Africa). Policy priorities are updated every two years and
presented in a full report, which includes individual country notes with detailed policy recommendations to
address the priorities. The next full report will be published in 2017.
This interim report takes stock of the actions taken by governments over the past year in the policy areas
identified as priorities for growth. This stocktaking is supported by internationally comparable indicators that
enable countries to assess their economic performance and structural policies in a wide range of areas.
Contents
Chapter 1. Overview of structural reforms in the policy areas identified as priorities for growth
Chapter 2. Reform priorities in a difficult macro context
Chapter 3. From GDP to average household income: A look at the transmission channels
Chapter 4. Structural policy indicators
Consult this publication on line at
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2016-en.
This work is published on the
OECD iLibrary,
which gathers all OECD books, periodicals and statistical databases.
Visit
www.oecd-ilibrary.org
for more information.
ISSN 1813-2715
2016 SUBSCRIPTION
ISBN 978-92-64-25007-9
12 2016 01 1 P