Kulturudvalget 2015-16
KUU Alm.del Bilag 48
Offentligt
1576773_0001.png
SpORtS GOveRnAnce
ObSeRveR 2015
the legitimacy crisis in international sports governance
Report / October 2015
Arnout Geeraert
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Play the Game
2
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
SPORTS GOVERNANCE
OBSERVER 2015
THE LEGITIMACY CRISIS IN
INTERNATIONAL SPORTS GOVERNANCE
Play the Game
3
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Title
Sports governance observer 2015. The legitimacy crisis in international sports governance
Author
Arnout Geeraert
Cover photo
Thomas Søndergaard
Print
Mercoprint Digital A/S
Edition
First edition, Copenhagen, October 2015
Price
A printed version of the report can be ordered from the Danish Institute for Sports Studies, price DKK
200 (delivery excluded). The report is available for free download at www.playthegame.org.
ISBN
978-87- 93375-18-5 (printed)
978-87- 93375-19-2 (pdf)
Publisher
Play the Game
c/o Danish Institute for Sports Studies
Kanonbådsvej 4A
DK-1437 København K
T: +45 3266 1030
E: [email protected]
W: www.idan.dk
W: www.playthegame.org
Quoting from this report is allowed with proper acknowledgements
Play the Game
4
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Content 
Executive summary ...........................................................................................................................7
 
Part I. Background and introduction ............................................................................................ 11
 
1. The AGGIS Project and the Sports Governance Observer tool .........................................11
 
Part II. Study: The legitimacy crisis in international sports governance..................................12
 
1. Introduction .............................................................................................................................. 12
 
2. Background ............................................................................................................................... 13
 
2.1 Transformations in international sports governance ....................................................13
 
2.2 The legitimacy crisis in international sports governance .............................................14
 
3. Methodology............................................................................................................................. 21
 
3.1 Legitimacy deficits as a problem of institutional design: the PA model ....................21
 
3.2 Data collection .................................................................................................................... 25
 
4. Analysis ..................................................................................................................................... 25
 
4.1 Delegation of authority to ISFs ........................................................................................25
 
4.2 Screening and selection mechanisms – main findings ..................................................28
 
4.3 Monitoring and reporting requirements – main findings ............................................29
 
4.4 Administrative procedures – main findings ..................................................................30
 
4.5 Institutional checks – main findings................................................................................32
 
4.6 Elections – main findings .................................................................................................. 33
 
5. Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 35
 
Part III. Sports Governance Observer survey ..............................................................................36
 
1. Introduction .............................................................................................................................. 36
 
2. Methodology............................................................................................................................. 36
 
3. The four dimensions of the Sports Governance Observer .................................................38
 
3.1 Dimension 1. TRANSPARENCY AND PUBLIC COMMUNICATION .....................40
 
3.2 Dimension 2. DEMOCRATIC PROCESS ........................................................................52
 
3.3 Dimension 3. CHECKS AND BALANCES.....................................................................61
 
3.4 Dimension 4. SOLIDARITY ..............................................................................................68
 
4. Results of the Sports Governance Observer survey ............................................................75
 
4.1 Overall results..................................................................................................................... 75
 
AIBA – International Boxing Association .............................................................................77
 
BWF – Badminton World Federation ....................................................................................78
 
FEI – Fédération Equestre Internationale The SGO index for FEI is 75.6%. ....................79
 
FIBA – International Basketball Federation..........................................................................80
 
Play the Game
5
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
FIBT – International Bobsleigh and Skeleton Federation ...................................................81
 
FIE - International Fencing Federation .................................................................................82
 
FIFA – Fédération Internationale de Football Association.................................................83
 
FIG – International Gymnastics Federation .........................................................................84
 
FIH – International Hockey Federation ................................................................................85
 
FIL – International Luge Federation ......................................................................................86
 
FINA – Fédération Internationale de Natation ....................................................................87
 
FIS – International Ski Federation .........................................................................................88
 
FISA – International Rowing Federation ..............................................................................89
 
FIVB – Fédération Internationale de Volleyball...................................................................90
 
IAAF – International Association of Athletics Federations................................................91
 
IBU – International Biathlon Union .......................................................................................92
 
ICF – International Canoe Federation ...................................................................................93
 
IGF – International Golf Federation ......................................................................................94
 
IHF – International Handball Federation .............................................................................95
 
IIHF – International Ice Hockey Federation .........................................................................96
 
IJF – International Judo Federation .......................................................................................97
 
ISAF – International Sailing Federation ................................................................................98
 
ISSF – International Shooting Sport Federation...................................................................99
 
ISU – International Skating Union ....................................................................................... 100
 
ITF – International Tennis Federation ................................................................................. 101
 
ITTF – International Table Tennis Federation .................................................................... 102
 
ITU – International Triathlon Union ................................................................................... 103
 
IWF – International Weightlifting Federation.................................................................... 104
 
UCI – Union Cycliste Internationale ................................................................................... 105
 
UIPM – Union Internationale de Pentathlon Moderne .................................................... 106
 
UWW – United World Wrestling......................................................................................... 107
 
WA – World Archery Federation......................................................................................... 108
 
WCF – World Curling Federation ....................................................................................... 109
 
WR - World Rugby ................................................................................................................ 110
 
WTF – World Taekwondo Federation................................................................................. 111
 
References ....................................................................................................................................... 116
 
Play the Game
6
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Executive summary 
This report presents the
Sports Governance Observer,
a benchmarking tool for good gov-
ernance in international sports federations based on basic good governance criteria, and its
application to the
35 Olympic international sports federations.
The report was commis-
sioned by Play the Game/Danish Institute for Sports Studies and executed by Dr. Arnout
Geeraert as a co-operation project between Play the Game/Danish Institute for Sports Stud-
ies and the University of Leuven.
The report consists of three main parts.
The first part
briefly explores the origins of this report. These are to be found in the Action
for Good Governance in International Sports Organisations (AGGIS) project, which re-
ceived financial support in 2012-2013 from the European Commission’s Preparatory Ac-
tions in the field of sport. The project produced a checklist of good governance elements for
international sports federations. This report elaborates this checklist into a practical
benchmarking tool with a scoring system.
The second part
presents an in-depth study of the governance of 35 Olympic sports federa-
tions. This study uses the data collected within the framework of the application of the
Sports Governance Observer survey to the 35 Olympic federations. The study explores how
corruption, unsatisfied internal stakeholders, and a (perceived) lack of effectiveness have
led to a crisis in the legitimacy of international sports federation, which may lead to insta-
bility and disorder in international sports governance. The study demonstrates that legiti-
macy crises are caused, first and foremost, by flawed institutional design; in particular, by a
lack of robust control mechanisms that allow both member federations and external actors
to control international sports federations. The main findings regarding the five categories
of control mechanisms identified in academic literature are:
1. Screening and selection mechanisms
Only four federations (11%) have a nominations committee in place that performs
integrity and professional checks.
A majority of 19 federations (54%) announce the candidates standing for election
one month or less before the elections take place. 32 federations (91%) announce
candidates standing for elections less than 2 months before they take place.
In only one federation, candidates are obliged to provide their manifesto.
2. Monitoring and reporting requirements
Only eight federations (23%) publish the agenda and minutes of its general
assembly on their website.
Only four federations (11%) publish governing body decisions on their website and
(sometimes) explain the rationale behind key decisions.
Play the Game
7
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Only six federations (17%) publish annual general activity reports on their websites
that include information on assets, accounts, revenue, sponsoring, and events.
Only eight federations (23%) publish (basic) reports of their standing committees
online.
None of the federations publishes reports on remuneration, including per diem
payments and bonuses, of its board members and senior officials.
A minority of 12 federations (35%) publishes externally audited annual financial
reports on its website.
3. Administrative procedures
For the 32 federations for which data was available, a majority of 18 federations
(56%) was found to have a code of ethics that includes crucial components such as
the prohibition of bribery and procedures covering the offer or receipt of gifts.
A minority of six (17%) federations have clear conflict of interest rules in place that
include disclosure requirements and the duty to abstain from voting in particular
cases, and define appropriate thresholds. Seven (20%) federations do not have con-
flict of interest rules in place at all.
In 18 of the 29 federations for which data was available (62%), the governing body
selects the host. Importantly, in none of the federations, the selection of host candi-
dates takes place according to a transparent and objectively reproducible process,
in which bidding dossiers are reviewed independently and assigned a score on the
basis of pre-established criteria.
In a majority of 23 federations (66%), the chairman/woman of the athletes’ com-
mission is a member of the decision-making body. However, in only eight federa-
tions (23%), athletes elect the chairman/woman of the athletes’ commission.
4. Institutional checks
12 federations (34%) do not have an ethics committee in place. Moreover, in only
five federations (14%), the ethics committee is robust, meaning that it is independ-
ent from the governing body and has the power to initiate proceedings on its own
initiative.
Only six federations (17%) have an internal audit committee that has a clearly de-
fined role and has the authority to oversee the internal audit and assesses the quali-
ty of the internal control system.
A minority of eight federations (23%) have an independent committee in place that
allows national federations, club, players, or official directly affected by a decision-
making body decision to appeal that decision.
5. Elections
In 23 federations (66%), elections take place according to clear and objective proce-
dures and secret ballots are used.
Play the Game
8
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0009.png
None of the federations has rules in place that limit the terms of office of the presi-
dent to two terms of four years and governing body members to two terms of four
years. However, 11 federations (31%) have some form of limitation in place.
These findings demonstrate that the majority of the 35 Olympic international sports federa-
tions do not have an institutional design implemented that allows their constituents to
monitor and sanction decision-making body members. Therefore, senior sports officials are
not sufficiently incentivised to act in accordance with their constituents’ interests.
In order to remedy the status quo,
the third part of this report
presents both the Sports
Governance Observer and the benchmarking of the 35 Olympic sports federations on the
basis of the tool. Introducing the
SGO index
as a measure of good governance, this part
exposes the strengths and weaknesses of each of the 35 federations in relation to good gov-
ernance.
It shows that the SGO index
1
of the 35 federations combined is 45.4% with 26 federations
(74%) scoring less than 50% (see Figure 1).
Figure 1: Sports Governance Observer 2015 scores 
SGO index
25%
0
FIS
FIFA
35%
45%
55%
65%
75%
FEI
5
10
15
20
25
30
ITU
FIL
IHF
UCI
AIBA
UIPM
ITTF
WR
FIG
WA (FITA)
WTF
FINA
FIBA
FIH
ICF
UWW
ISU
FIBT
WCF
IWF
IBU
FIVB
ITF
IJF
BWF
ISAF
FISA
IIHF
IAAF
FIE
Rank
35
IGF
ISSF
1
The SGO index indicates to what degree the federations comply with the 36 indicators constituted in the
four governance dimensions: transparency, democratic process, checks and balances, and solidarity. Con-
sequently, a federation getting the highest possible score (5) on all included indicators in this survey
would achieve an SGO index of 100%.
Play the Game
9
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0010.png
In general, the federations score weak to moderate on the four dimensions of good govern-
ance upon which the Sports Governance Observer is based, namely
transparency, demo-
cratic process, checks and balances,
and
solidarity
(see table 1).
Table 1: SGO Index and SGO scores – all 35 federations 
All 35 federations 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.99 
2.81 
2.68 
2.79 
 
SGO Index 
49.6% 
45.2% 
42.0% 
44.9% 
45.4% 
 
It must be stressed that the SGO index reflects the presence of
basic criteria of good gov-
ernance.
Medium-size federations should be expected to have an SGO index close to 75%,
while large federations should achieve a score higher than 75%. While having a high SGO
index does not rule out the occurrence of corruption, it can be expected that the absence of
basic criteria of good governance increases the likelihood of opportunistic and unethical
behaviour.
Play the Game/Danish Institute for Sports Studies invites
everyone with an interest in
sports governance, including (senior) sports and governmental officials, to contribute to
developing the Sports Governance Observer further in order to increase its robustness,
validity and reliability.
2
2
PhD Arnout Geeraerd, KU Leuven: [email protected]. Jens Sejer Andersen, International
Director, Play the Game: [email protected]
Play the Game
10
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Part I. Background and introduction 
1. The AGGIS Project and the Sports Governance Observer tool  
 
1.1 Action for Good Governance in International Sports Organisations (AGGIS) 
In 2012-2013, Play the Game/Danish Institute for Sports Studies cooperated with six Euro-
pean Universities (Loughborough University, Utrecht University, University of Leuven,
German Sport University Cologne, IDHEAP Lausanne, and Ljubljana University) and the
European Journalism Centre on the topic of good governance in international sports organ-
isations. The co-operation took place under the framework the Action for Good Govern-
ance in International Sports Organisations (AGGIS) project, which received financial sup-
port from the European Commission’s Preparatory Actions in the field of sport.
The project aimed to identify guidelines, stimulate the debate and analyse the state of af-
fairs with regard to good governance in international sports organisations. Its outcomes
have been published in a final report (Alm, 2013). One of the key features of this report is
the Sports Governance Observer, a checklist of elements that the experts deemed vital for
good governance in international sports federations (see AGGIS group, 2013).
1.2 The Sports Governance Observer 
After the funding period of the AGGIS project, Play the Game/Danish Institute for Sports
Studies decided to continue its efforts on the subject of good governance. It engaged in a
project with the University of Leuven with the aim and view of elaborating the Sports Gov-
ernance Observer from a checklist into a practical benchmarking tool with a scoring system
that can be used to assess the degree of good governance in international sports federa-
tions. In addition, the aim was to test the tool on a large group of federations. The results of
these efforts are presented in this report.
1.3 Aims and scope of the report  
The main aim of this report is to stimulate debate and disseminate good practice on the
issue of good governance in international sport. Everyone with an interest in sports gov-
ernance, including (senior) sports and governmental officials, is invited to contribute to
developing the Sports Governance Observer further in order to increase its robustness,
validity and reliability.
This report is divided in three main parts. After this introductory section, the second part
of the report presents an in-depth study of the governance of 35 Olympic sports federa-
tions. This study analyses the raw data collected within the framework of the Sports Gov-
ernance Observer survey. This adds to objectivity of the research. Indeed, the methodology
that underpins the Sports Governance Observer (i.e., constructing composite indicators) is
associated with making subjective choices and, therefore, the choice was made to also in-
clude in this report an analysis on the basis of the unprocessed data of the 35 federations.
The third part comprises both the Sports Governance Observer tool and the results of its
application on the 35 Olympic sports federations.
Play the Game
11
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0012.png
Part II. Study: The legitimacy crisis in international sports 
governance
3
 
1. Introduction 
When international sports federations (ISFs) emerged at the turn of the twentieth century,
few actors questioned their legitimacy. On the contrary, there was a clear need for global
regulators for sport: increased international competition required clear and consistent
rules. Over the years, ISFs’ functional importance has continued to increase. ISFs proved
extremely useful: they possess functional qualities and expertise. Most notably, they pro-
vide order and structure to the complex sporting world through regulations, licenses, poli-
cies, and so on. Yet transformations in international sports governance have led to a more
commercialised setting, in which ISFs struggle to maintain their legitimacy. Corruption,
unsatisfied internal stakeholders, and a perceived lack of effectiveness have led stakehold-
ers to contest ISFs’ legitimacy.
This study argues that three forms of ISFs’ legitimacy are under threat, namely output le-
gitimacy, procedural legitimacy, and structural legitimacy. Because they fail to reflect af-
fected audiences’ expectations, ISFs develop legitimacy deficits in these three dimensions.
Aware that their legitimacy is under threat, ISFs engage in three practices in order to
(re-)claim and sustain legitimacy: self-legitimation, horizontal legitimation, which involves
engaging in partnerships with political actors, and institutional reform. These legitimation
efforts have however failed to fully address legitimacy gaps. In certain ISFs, this has led to
severe legitimacy crises because they face disempowerment, which may lead to instability
and disorder in international sports governance.
The study demonstrates that legitimacy crises are caused, first and foremost, by flawed
institutional design. It introduces the so-called Principal-Agent model in order to analyse
ISFs’ organisational structures. In order to reclaim legitimacy, ISFs must engage in thor-
ough institutional reforms and install a number of robust control mechanisms that allow
for monitoring and sanctioning senior sports officials’ behaviour.
This study continues as follows. The second section of this chapter explores how transfor-
mations in international sports governance have caused legitimacy gaps and crises in rela-
tion to ISFs. The third
section lays out the methodology of the study. It introduces the
Prin-
cipal-Agent
model to test the hypothesis that the
institutional design of ISFs is flawed. The
fourth section applies the Principal-Agent model in order to analyse the institutional de-
sign of ISFs. The analysis relies on data collected from the 35 Olympic ISFs. The final
sections summarises the findings and makes a number of policy recommendations.
3
This study is to be regarded as a working paper. If at all possible, please quote more final versions of the
study.
Play the Game
12
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
2. Background 
2.1 Transformations in international sports governance 
At the turn of the twentieth century, international competition spurred the need to central-
ise sports governance and to unify rules, paving the way for the first ISFs. The creation and
success of the modern Olympic Games, for instance, increased international competition
(Chappelet and Kübler-Mabbott, 2008, p. 64). The international sport governance system
that soon crystallised can generally be described as a hierarchical network running from
the global to continental, national, and local levels. In broad terms, for a single sport, an
international federation stands at the top of a vertical chain of command (Geeraert, 2016a).
ISFs were able to consolidate their monopolies as global regulating bodies for their respec-
tive sports because they fulfilled the need for consistent rules. Because the public sector has
long regarded sport a cultural and, above all, amateur activity, international sports govern-
ance has also remained largely private in nature. The sports world claims that the regula-
tion of sport is best kept private (Chappelet, 2010). This has not prevented politics from co-
opting sport (Jackson and Haigh, 2009). In recent years, this symbiosis has become particu-
larly visible in the politics and policies of the so-called emerging countries, which tend to
see sport mega-events as “proxies for integration and influence” (Cornelissen, 2010, p.
3015). The instrumentalisation of sport by politics is said to have led, at times, to improper
influence and the concentration of power in ISFs, inducing the corrosion of the ethical
character of international sports governance (Voy and Deeter, 1992; Weinreich, 2014a).
Even though they have allowed politics to influence their policies and decisions, autonomy
from formal regulatory public interference is an obsession for ISFs (Geeraert, Mrkonjic and
Chappelet, 2014). Modern sport’s construction is, in essence, rooted in classic liberalism,
namely in the concept of freedom of association (Szymanski, 2006). Autonomy is therefore
a deeply ingrained and cherished principle in the sports world. It is an essential part of
ISFs’ belief system; a doctrine that they aim to spread among political institutions and
stakeholders in order to keep the governance of international sport strictly private. Re-
markably, however, the sports world has never formulated a clear definition or justification
of the autonomy of sport (cf. IOC, 2008, p. 1). Autonomy is a concept that is deliberately
kept vague in order to function as a passe-partout to justify self-governance. Yet in the past
two decades, many facets of ISFs’ self-governance have come under increasing pressure.
The commercialisation of sport can be cited as a direct cause of this trend.
The origins of the commercialisation of sport can be traced to the period after the Second
World War, when more individual leisure time led to both more opportunities to practice
(organised) sport and an increased consumption of sport (Andreff, 2008). The development
of radio and, later on, television broadcasting even allowed for remote consumption of
sport events. Television broadcasting boosted the popularity of certain sports and fuelled
the global popularity of related sport events. However, the enormous commercial impact
of sports broadcasting only hit when a privatisation wave broke up public broadcasting
monopolies in Europe during the 1980s. Together with these evolutions, the development
of cable, satellite and digital television and the internet boosted the demand for sports
Play the Game
13
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
broadcasting from the 1990s on, resulting in more valuable broadcasting deals for sporting
events (Andreff and Staudohar, 2000; Andreff and Bourg, 2006; Szymanski, 2006). Against
this background, the largest ISFs have increasingly realised the business potential of their
sporting events. Since the mid-1980s, they have marketed their events more effectively,
selling exclusive marketing rights – mostly through agencies – for vast sums of money
(Tomlinson, 2005; Chappelet and Kübler-Mabott, 2008). In this light, ISFs have also benefit-
ted from the revenue generated by the Olympic Games, which the International Olympic
Committee (IOC) redistributes among associated federations (Chappelet and Kübler-
Mabott, 2008).
The commercialisation of sport has put the autonomy of ISFs under increased pressure.
Reasons for this are fourfold:
Firstly, the increase in revenue has incentivised opportunistic senior sports officials
to behave unethically. A number of officials have engaged in racketeering, wire
fraud, money laundering, and taking bribes.
Secondly, as sport emerged from its initial amateur status and governance chal-
lenges became more complex, the impact of ISFs’ policies and decisions on public
and private actors and society at large increased accordingly. This has resulted in
affected actors undertaking actions to increase their influence on the governance of
international sport (Geeraert, 2016b).
Thirdly, sport is increasingly infiltrated by (international) criminal activities.
Fourthly, a trend towards ‘gigantism’ in relation to large sporting events has raised
questions regarding sustainability (Chappelet and Kübler-Mabbott, 2008, p. 80;
Geeraert, 2016c).
These issues, and the general failure of ISFs to provide adequate solutions, have put the
legitimacy
of ISFs to govern sport autonomously at an international level under severe
stress.
2.2 The legitimacy crisis in international sports governance 
According to Zaum, “[a]n institution is legitimate if its power is justified in terms of moral
and socially embedded beliefs, and if those subject to its rule recognise that it should be
obeyed” (Zaum, 2013, p. 9). This definition reflects the meaning of legitimacy as “a social
status that can adhere to an actor or action” and which is “recognized as good, proper, or
commendable by a group of others” (Coleman, 2007, p. 20). It also highlights the im-
portance of specific audiences in judging whether an institution is legitimate. Yet for a giv-
en institution to lack
legitimacy
is not the same as lacking
support
from affected audiences.
Indeed, on order to be legitimate, an institution must be
perceived
as legitimate (Frost, 2013,
p. 27). When an institution’s practices and objectives fail to reflect affected audiences’ moral
and socially embedded beliefs, it develops a
legitimacy deficit
(Zaum, 2013, p. 7). Affected
audiences perceive the institution as illegitimate, and this may give rise to a
legitimacy crisis
Play the Game
14
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
when legitimacy “declines to the point where the actor or institution must either adapt […]
or face disempowerment” (Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 158).
Recently, a number of ISFs have developed severe legitimacy deficits. In certain cases, these
even gave rise to legitimacy crises. In order to assess these deficits, this section relies on
Zaum (2013), who distinguishes three different forms of legitimacy, namely
output legitima-
cy, procedural legitimacy,
and
structural legitimacy.
ISF’s legitimacy deficits are especially
situated in the former two dimensions. Their structural legitimacy, though challenged by
internal stakeholders, remains largely uncontested by political actors.
Output legitimacy
Firstly,
output legitimacy
refers to beliefs about an institution’s effectiveness to produce de-
sired outcomes and promote shared goals. ISFs have largely failed to adequately deal with
an increasing number of governance challenges that came with the commercialisation and
the resulting complexity of the sports world. Almost inevitably, the commercialisation of
sport has been at the basis of significant failures of governance (Henry and Lee, 2004).
These failures are not unique to sport. They reflect the challenges modern public govern-
ance faces in the light of an increasingly complex society and include both too little and too
much regulation, flawed policy designs, (political) gridlocks and cooperation failures (cf.
Bovens, ‘t Hart and Peters, 2001). For instance, ISFs have largely been unable to unilaterally
deal with transnational governance issues, such as doping, match-fixing and criminal net-
works targeting sports (Houlihan, 1999; Bakadiababu, 2001; Hill, 2010). In addition, the
potential positive effects of large sporting events on local populations are undermined by
the lack of sustainability requirements for host countries (Geeraert, 2016c). Finally, due to
the increased commercial and economic significance of sports, activities of ISFs fall within
the scope of and often breach economic laws at different levels (Parrish, 2003; Parrish and
McArdle, 2004). Such failures of governance in sport have prompted the debate for more
public oversight and control over the sports world. Public authorities at different levels
have been contesting, competing, and cooperating with ISFs (Houlihan, 1999; Henry and
Lee, 2004; Croci and Forster, 2004; Chappelet, 2010; Geeraert, 2016b).
Procedural legitimacy
Secondly,
procedural legitimacy
pertains beliefs about whether or not an institution’s internal
workings conform to generally accepted procedures. Sports governance is characterised by
a hierarchical pyramid structure that runs from the global to continental, national, and lo-
cal levels (Geeraert, 2016a). As a general rule, an ISF stands at the top of a vertical chain of
command for each individual sport. Usually, continental sport federations are housed un-
der the global federation. National federations, in turn, are housed beneath the continental
federations. At the lowest end of the chain are clubs (when the sport in question is a team
sport) and athletes who take part in the competitions. They must conform to the rules
adopted at the top end of the pyramid.
As sport transitioned from its initial amateur status and governance challenges became
more complex, ISFs increasingly adopted more (diverse) tasks on behalf of their internal
Play the Game
15
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
stakeholders (Geeraert, 2016b). For instance, ISFs issue rules that determine the conditions
for athlete transfers between clubs; the conditions clubs and athletes must fulfil to enter
competition; the modalities surrounding competition; doping use; and the redistribution of
revenue. Sport organisations can sanction athletes, clubs, and national federations for
breaching these rules through their disciplinary bodies. Directly affected by and cognizant
of the augmented powers of ISFs, internal stakeholders, have responded to the organisa-
tions’ increasing reach. Athletes, clubs, and national federations have voiced grievances
about their lack of participation and decision-making power in the policy processes of ISFs.
In certain cases, this has resulted in the emancipation of international sport organisation’s
internal stakeholders (Holt 2006; García, 2007; Thibault et al., 2010). Yet the danger exists
that the most powerful stakeholders are favoured to the detriment of those that have less
clout but are nevertheless equally affected by the policies devised by ISFs (Geeraert, 2016b).
The issue that most severely challenges ISFs’ procedural legitimacy, however, is corrup-
tion. A range of high-profile ethical scandals spurred public attention for corruption within
ISFs. These scandals seem to point to unfair, opaque and unaccountable internal (voting)
procedures, including regarding the awarding of sport events. The most notable examples
of corruption are the 2002 Olympic Winter Games bid scandal, which involved allegations
of bribery used to win the rights to host the 2002 Winter Olympics in Salt Lake City (Mal-
lon, 2000), and the litany of corruption-related indictments enveloping FIFA, the governing
body of football (Jennings, 2006; Weinreich, 2014b). On 27 May 2015, US authorities indict-
ed fourteen officials on racketeering, wire fraud, and money laundering charges. Seven
current FIFA officials (including one FIFA Vice-President) were arrested by the Swiss au-
thorities at the request of the US Department of Justice on suspicion of receiving $150 mil-
lion in bribes in return for media and marketing rights during FIFA related events in North
and South America. US and Swiss authorities subsequently initiated separate criminal in-
vestigations into the awarding of the 2018 and 2022 football World Cup hosting rights to
Russia and Qatar, respectively (Gibson, 2015).
Allegations of corruption or other forms of ‘governance failures’ are however not unique to
the largest sport organisation. Three examples below can serve to illustrate how a number
of smaller ISFs are affected by similar problems. Mexican Ruben Acosta allegedly got away
with at least $33 million in personal commissions in the last decade of his 24 years reign as
president of the International Volleyball Federation (Hoy, 2005). Hassan Moustafa, the
Egyptian President of the International Handball Federation, received over 300,000 euro in
travel reimbursement without presenting receipts. He also established a salary raise (from
a part-time fee of 30,000 Swiss Franc to an annual 500,000 Swiss Franc as a full-time em-
ployee) and his fellow board members (a 500 % increase) so that they receive more than the
International Handball Federation’s total development aid. Moreover, he allegedly secured
a personal contract worth 602,000 euro with German sports marketing company Sportfive,
which later acquired the IHF broadcasting rights (Ahl, 2009; 2010; 2013). Finally, in the In-
ternational Weightlifting Federation, Hungarian Tamas Aján, who has been president for
15 years, failed to account for the disappearance of an estimated $5 million of IOC grants
from two Swiss bank accounts (Hartmann, 2013).
Play the Game
16
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
As a result of especially the high-profile ethical scandals in FIFA, public actors have in-
creasingly started to express their discontent with ISFs’ governance. National parliaments,
the European Parliament and the Parliamentary Assembly of the Council of Europe called
upon ISFs, in particular FIFA, to improve their governance (Randall and Brady, 2011; UK
Parliament, 2011; Parliamentary assembly of the Council of Europe, 2012; European Par-
liament, 2013; European Parliament, 2015). Following the most recent FIFA corruption
scandal, British Prime Minister David Cameron and Culture Secretary John Whittingdale
called for reforms in FIFA (BBC, 2015).
Structural legitimacy
Thirdly,
structural legitimacy
refers to beliefs about whether or not an institution is “the
right organisation for the job” (Sutchman, 1995, p. 582). Internal stakeholders have chal-
lenged the legitimacy of their respective ISFs’ governing monopoly. In several sports, ISFs
protect their governing monopoly in order to deny their members the right to take part in
alternative sport events that are not officially sanctioned by the federation. Profitable, al-
ternative competition formats outside ISFs’ regulatory scope have nonetheless been pro-
posed and have emerged in recent years. Most recently, the International Skating Union
banned two Dutch speed skaters for life for participating in a profitable new competition in
Dubai (Rossing, 2014). The most notable example of a (possible) breakaway competition
has however occurred in football. In 1998, a private business group planned to set up a
highly profitable European super league competition outside of FIFA and UEFA’s struc-
tures (Holt, 2006, pp. 35-36). The plan was abandoned when UEFA agreed to reform its
premier European club championship Champions League so that elite European clubs
could gain more revenue. However, secession threats by elite European clubs continue to
emerge from time to time.
ISFs’ structural legitimacy has however been less challenged by public actors. Two reasons
can be cited for this. Firstly, as already noted, ISFs and the IOC have successfully promoted
the idea among political institutions that an autonomous sports movement is necessary for
the proper organisation of sport (Geeraert, 2016a). The sports worlds’ lobbying powers are
determined by a number of (sport) specific features. Sport is very popular with politicians,
who try to win votes by associating themselves with sporting events. Moreover, national
sports federations often have strong ties with their national government, and ISFs can capi-
talise on this (Geeraert and Drieskens, 2015a). Finally, ISFs can capitalise on their regulato-
ry powers in order to influence politics. Indeed, they important means of reprisal against
national public authorities, which they can use in order to keep these authorities under
control. ISFs can exact costs on a country by blocking it from participating in international
competitions by suspending its national sport federation. Moreover, they can withdraw the
privilege of hosting sporting events such as the World Cup or the Euro (Kędzior and
Szczepanik, 2012, p. 212). Finally, acting contrary to the wishes of the IOC and ISFs may be
detrimental for bids to host major events (García and Weatherill, 2012, p. 249). As already
mentioned, hosting (large) sporting events has become increasingly important to national
governments.
Play the Game
17
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0018.png
The second reason why public actors have not severely challenged ISFs’ structural legiti-
macy is that ISFs’ are, at least in principle, extremely useful organisations. The recognition
of their functional qualities and expertise contributes to their legitimacy (Geeraert, 2016b;
see also Cutler, Haufler and Porter [1999]). First, as the custodians of sport, they are – in
principle – the only actors that can take into account the interests of sport as a whole. Other
sport stakeholders have separate interests that do not necessarily serve the general
(sporting) interest. ISFs effectuate cooperation between (internal) stakeholders, ensuring
that they all move in the same (mutually beneficial) direction. Related, whereas (internal)
stakeholders are unlikely to reach a stable agreement on policy, ISFs allow for
collective
decision-making
by controlling the agenda of sports governance. Second, they are specialised
bodies that are supposed to culminate the necessary expertise to govern sporting issues.
They provide
specialisation
in that they have the expertise, time and resources to oversee
sport competition. They are also useful in that they offer
dispute resolution
between internal
stakeholders. Third, they have an important state-like function in bringing
order and struc-
ture
the complex sporting world through regulations, licenses, policies, and so on. At the
global level, no overarching state authority exists that is capable of fulfilling this role
(Geeraert, 2016a, p. 423).
The resultant belief on the part of political institutions in the appropriateness of having
private monopolies govern sport has not been severely damaged as a result of sports
corruption.
4
Tellingly, in the aftermath of the FIFA corruption scandal, virtually no
politicians suggested that the organisation’s governing monopoly should be overthrown.
One significant exception to this rule is the creation of the World Anti-Doping Agency
(WADA). WADA was conceived as a hybrid, public-private organisation because public
authorities requested a more significant role as they were sceptical about the IOC after the
2002 Salt Lake City corruption scandal (Houlihan, 2001, p. 125).
Legitimation efforts by ISFs
For an institution to be legitimate, it must claim and sustain its legitimacy so that it is
recognised as rightful. Institutions seeking legitimacy therefore constantly “justify their
identities, interests, practices, or institutional designs” (Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 159). ISFs have
engaged in such processes. They have responded to legitimacy deficits by engaging in
legitimation practices, which pertain to “conscious efforts” to enhance and sustain their
legitimacy (Welsh and Zaum, 2013, p. 71).
Three broad practices stand out:
self-legitimation, horizontal legitimation,
and
institutional
reform:
Firstly, ISFs engage in
self-legitimation,
which refers to “an action or series of actions
– speech, writing, ritual, display – whereby people justify to themselves or others
the actions they are taking and the identities they are expressing or claiming”
4
However, note that both international and national sports federations’ structural legitimacy is
increasingly challenged by their inability to promote sport for all and their resultant loss of market share
in the sport for all market.
Play the Game
18
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0019.png
(Barker, 2003, pp. 163-164). As mentioned, ISFs and the IOC often proclaim their le-
legitimacy in their discourse by referring to the autonomy of sport. A good example
is a position paper of the Olympic and sports movement on the autonomy of sport,
in which it is stresses that “[t]he responsibility sport has in society, and the
autonomy with which it regulates itself, have led to its credibility and legitimacy.
Autonomy thus means preserving the values of sport and the existing structures
through which it has developed in Europe and in the world” (IOC, 2008, p. 1).
Secondly, ISFs engage in
horizontal legitimation,
which pertains to “legitimation by
actors who are outside the hierarchical relationship governed by legitimacy”
(Zaum, 2013, p. 11). An established strategy in this regard has been to engage in
‘partnerships’ with (international) political actors such as the United Nations and
the European Union in order to solidify legitimacy credentials (cf. Williams, 2013,
p. 43). By associating with these actors, ISFs gain status and recognitions; they can
adopt some of the authority derived from the legitimacy of these institutions (cf.
Hurd, 2002, p. 43). ISFs benefit from the fact that the IOC has accumulated
international legitimacy by associating itself with the United Nations. Since 2009,
the IOC even enjoys observer status in the United Nations General Assembly and
in April 2014, a Memorandum of Understanding was signed between UN
Secretary-General Ban Ki-moon and the IOC. The agreement stresses that the
United Nations and the IOC “share the same values of contributing to a better and
peaceful world through sport” and “calls for respect of the autonomous
organisation of sport” (IOC, 2014). ISFs such as FIFA, the International Judo
Federation, the International Bobsleigh and Skeleton Federation, the Badminton
World Federation, the International Biathlon Union, the International Association
of Athletics Federations, and the International Volleyball Federation and
SportAccord, the umbrella organisation of more than 100 ISFs, have engaged in
similar partnerships with the United Nations (IOC, 2010; 2011; 2012; 2013a; BWF,
2015; IAAF, 2015; UNESCO, 2015).
5
ISFs, continental federations and umbrella
organisations of sport federations have also been keen to associate themselves and
engage in partnership agreements with the European Union for reasons of
legitimation (Geeraert, 2016b).
Thirdly, in recent years, a number of ISFs have openly
reformed their internal
workings
in order to enhance their legitimacy. For instance, they have engaged in
governance reforms, aimed at enhancing transparency and accountability. When
doing so, they have often communicated these changes extensively to their internal
stakeholders and the general public. The most prominent examples in this regard
are the internal reforms that took place within the IOC after the Salt Lake City
scandal in 1999 and the recent FIFA reform process that followed numerous reports
of corruption (Chappelet and Kübler-Mabbott, 2008; Pieth, 2014a). Most recently,
Wilfried Lemke, the United Nations Secretary-General’s Special Adviser on Sport for Development and
Peace in fact encourages such partnerships: “We need partnership between the world of sport and United
Nations to harness the full potential that sport has to be an agent for social change.” (Lemke in IOC, 2010).
5
Play the Game
19
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0020.png
Union Cycliste Internationale (UCI), the world governing body for sports cycling,
has announced that it will engage in governance reforms (UCI, 2015). The problem
with these reforms is that a generally accepted and objective benchmark is lacking
in order to evaluate if these reforms adequately address accountability and
transparency deficiencies or if they merely serve as window-dressing (Geeraert,
2015). In addition, ISFs have formally institutionalised the consultation of internal
stakeholders, in particular athletes (Geeraert, Alm and Grohl, 2014; Geeraert,
2016b).
The importance of resolving legitimacy gaps and crises
The legitimation efforts by ISFs have failed to fully address legitimacy gaps. Only when an
institution’s legitimacy claims are recognised as rightful does it command legitimacy
(Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 159). Affected audiences, particularly NGOs, internal stakeholders, and
parliamentary assemblies continue to challenge ISFs’ output and procedural legitimacy.
ISFs fail to reflect these audiences’ beliefs on procedural fairness and effectiveness. In
certain ISFs, this has led to severe legitimacy crises because “the level of social recognition”
that their identities, interests, practices, norms, or procedures “are rightful declines to the
point where the actor or institution must either adapt […] or face disempowerment” (Reus-
Smit, 2007, p. 158).
The most well-known example is FIFA, but the governance failures including the cases of
corruption mentioned above indicate that international sports governance faces a severe
legitimacy crisis.
6
This crisis is chronic, since legitimacy deficits remain severe, but the
compensatory use of short-term legitimation strategies “stave off disempowerment without
recalibrating the social bases of legitimacy” (Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 168). Consequently, these
strategies are not sustainable. The danger therefore exists that international sports
governance is increasingly confronted with stability and disorder (cf. Reus-Smit, 2007, p.
170). Indeed, as indicated, ISFs are pivotal actors in international sports governance
because of their functional qualities and expertise. The disempowerment of ISFs moreover
bears costs for society at large. A failure to address issues such as doping, match-fixing,
money laundering, a lack of (environmental) sustainability, corruption, and the illegal
trade in African and South American athletes has a negative impact on the wider
community.
It is thus extremely important that the legitimacy crisis in international sport is resolved,
both for those involved in professional and grassroots sport and those that have nothing to
do with sport as such. How do we resolve this crisis? In what follows, it will be shown that
ISFs’ legitimacy deficit is essentially a problem of
flawed institutional design.
Put simply, ISFs often lack legitimacy because, in general, they are characterised by ‘bad
governance’.
6
Note that the IOC was confronted with a severe legitimacy crisis after the Salt Lake City corruption scan-
dal (see above).
Play the Game
20
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0021.png
3. Methodology 
3.1 Legitimacy deficits as a problem of institutional design: the principal‐agent 
model 
How do we resolve the legitimacy crisis in international sports governance in a sustainable
manner?
In order to make sure that ISFs conduct their tasks in such a way that they are recognised
as legitimate, their actions and interests need to be recalibrated with the normative
expectations of their social constituency of legitimation. Put differently, ISFs’ actions need
to “resonate with the normative expectations” of those that are affected by ISFs’ actions
(Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 172). This raises the question how we can make sure that ISFs’ act in
the best interest of stakeholders. In order to answer this question, we must conceptualise
and theorise the problem. This study relies on the insights of the Principal-Agent (PA)
model, which has proven a powerful tool to analyse relationships where an actor or group
of actors (the agent(s)) behaves on behalf of another actor or set of actors (the principal(s)).
7
In organisational studies, the Principal-Agent model is “fundamentally concerned with
institutional design” (Elgie, 2002, p. 189). In brief, actors (the
principals)
delegate tasks to an
institution (the
agent),
and expect the institution to behave in their best interest when
executing these tasks. However, the principals cannot fully observe and do not have
information on the appropriateness of all the actions of the agent. The agent, moreover, has
its own private interests that do not necessarily correspond with those of the principals,
and which incentivise the agent to behave opportunistically and pursue its own interests.
This gives rise to
agency slack
or
independent action by the agent that is undesired by the
principal.
Slack can take different forms. It can refer to inertia, inefficiency and/or
ineffectiveness, but also to corruption. The challenge of institutional design is thus to
construct agencies in such a way so as to minimise slack (Pollack, 1997, p. 101; Elgie, 2002,
p. 189; Majone, 1999). Indeed, institutions impose rules-based constraints on actors and
therefore structure the behaviour of actors.
This brings us to the question of how institutions can be designed so that agency slack is
minimised. This question of institutional design is in essence a problem associated with the
Principal-Agent model: how can we structure relationships between the principal and the
agent so that the outcomes of the agent’s actions comply with the principal’s wishes (cf.
Majone, 1999, p. 13)? Principal-Agent analysis holds that
control mechanisms
can alter the
The Principal-Agent model mostly relies on the theoretical assumptions of rational choice theory. Ration-
al choice theory assumes that actors behave rationally and instrumentally in order to maximise the attain-
ment of their self-interests (Snidal, 1985, p. 40). More specifically, this study finds resonance with
rational
choice institutionalism,
which holds that institutions impose rules-based constraints on actors and thus
structure the behaviour of actors, and these actors hold a fixed set of preferences and behave instrumental-
ly. Importantly, the Principal-Agent model should not be seen as a dogma or aim in itself. A useful alter-
native option to study actor behaviour in ISFs would be to use a constructivist approach, which explores
the existence of informal norms that shape actors’ identities and preferences within institutions. Such an
approach can even be complementary with the rational choice approach used in this study (cf. Geeraert
and Drieskens, 2015b).
7
Play the Game
21
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
incentives of the agent such that acting in line with the principal’s interests is more attrac-
attractive (McCubbins and Schwartz, 1984; Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991; Pollack, 1997;
Geeraert and Drieskens, 2015a). Such control mechanisms should comprise a mixture of
monitoring
and
sanctioning:
1. By
monitoring
the agent’s actions, the principal decreases information asymmetries
concerning the agent’s actions and interests. This decreases the likelihood that slack
will go unnoticed. In addition, knowing that the principal is observing its actions,
the agent will be motivated to act in the principal’s best interest.
2.
Sanctions
entail imposing costs on the agent. The mere acknowledgement of the
credible possibility of a sanction “provides a measure of latent control over the
agent’s actions” (Calvert, McCubbins and Weingast, 1989, p. 604). If demonstrating
slack leads to costs for the agent, than the agent will be incentivised not to act
contrary to the principal’s interests.
If monitoring and sanctioning mechanisms are installed in institutions, acting in the
principals’ interests will be made a more attractive option. More specifically, five distinct
classes of measures that are particularly relevant for the present purposes emerge from the
Principal-Agent literature (i.e., monitoring and sanctioning) the agent (Calvert, McCubbins
and Weingast, 1989; Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991; Pollack, 1997; Fearon, 1999). These are
(1)
screening and selection mechanisms,
(2)
monitoring and reporting requirements,
(3)
administrative procedures,
(4)
institutional checks,
and (5)
elections.
ISFs that have measures
implemented in their institutional design are expected to demonstrate high degrees of
legitimacy. Reasons for this are threefold:
1. They allow for the calibration of agent actions with the normative expectations of
those that are represented (i.e., the principals) (cf. Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 172).
2. They contribute to outcome legitimacy because they increase institutions’
effectiveness. The reason for this is that, firstly, recognition of legitimacy translates
into voluntary compliance by stakeholders (Reus-Smit, 2007, p. 170). Secondly,
administrative procedures that allow for the inclusion of principals in the decision
making process may lead to more effective governance because they can provide
specialized knowledge (Klijn and Koppenjan, 2004). Thirdly, increased
accountability enhances the learning capacity and effectiveness of organisations
(Aucoin and Heintzman 2000, Bovens 2007).
3. They enhance institutions’ procedural legitimacy because they improve the quality
of internal procedures. Firstly, they provide principals’ with statutory options for
control and thus contribute to the fairness and openness of (and, thus, trust in) the
internal working of the institution (Mouffe, 1993; Vaubel, 2006, p. 129). Secondly,
control mechanisms and procedures decrease the likelihood of agents engaging in
unethical behaviour such as corruption and fraud (Ades and Di Tella, 1997, p. 508).
Play the Game
22
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0023.png
The Principal-Agent model predicts that, in the absence of control mechanisms, the agent
will minimise its efforts on behalf of the principal and even pursue its own interests at the
expense of the principal (McCubbins and Page, 1987, pp. 410-411; Pollack, 2003, p. 26). This
necessarily leads to legitimacy gaps and crises. This logic can also be inversed. Given the
legitimacy gaps and crises in international sports governance, it can be expected that the
institutional design of ISFs is flawed in the sense they lack monitoring and sanctioning
mechanisms.
The remainder of this report tests this hypothesis.
The decision was made to focus
on the 35 ISFs whose sports will be represented at the 2016 Olympic Games (see Table 1).
Although these federations vary considerably in terms of size, amount of revenue
generated and popularity of their respective sports, they are comparable because they
represent popular summer and winter sport and benefit from the IOC’s redistribution
scheme.
 Table 2: Population of the study: the 35 Olympic ISFs 
English name 
International Boxing  
Association 
Badminton World  
Federation 
International Federation 
for Equestrian Sports 
International Basketball 
Federation 
International Bobsleigh & 
Skeleton Federation 
International Fencing  
Federation 
Acronym 
AIBA 
BWF 
FEI 
FIBA 
FIBT 
FIE 
Summer/winter 
Olympic sport 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Summer 
Registered 
Office 
Lausanne 
Country 
Co‐operated 
with research 
Switzerland  No 
Yes 
Kuala Lumpur  Malaysia 
Lausanne 
Geneva 
Lausanne 
Lausanne 
Zürich 
Lausanne 
Lausanne 
Berchtesgade
Lausanne 
Switzerland  Yes 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  Yes 
Switzerland  Yes 
Switzerland  No 
Germany 
No 
International Federation of  FIFA 
Association Football 
International Federation of  FIG 
Gymnastics 
International Hockey  
Federation 
International Luge  
Federation 
International Swimming 
Federation 
International Ski  
Federation 
FIH 
FIL 
FINA 
FIS 
Switzerland  No 
Oberhofen 
Switzerland  Yes 
am Thunersse 
Lausanne 
Lausanne 
Switzerland  Yes 
Switzerland  No 
International Federation of  FISA 
Rowing Associations 
World Archery Federation 
FITA/ WA 
Play the Game
23
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0024.png
International Volleyball 
Federation 
International Association 
of Athletics Federations 
FIVB 
IAAF 
Summer 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Summer 
Winter 
Summer 
Summer 
Lausanne 
Monaco 
Salzburg 
Lausanne 
Lausanne 
Basle 
Zürich 
Lausanne 
Switzerland  No 
Monaco 
Austria 
No 
Yes 
Internation Biathlon Union  IBU 
International Canoe  
Federation 
International Golf  
Federation 
International Handball 
Federation 
International Ice Hockey 
Federation 
International Judo  
Federation 
International Sailing  
Federation Limited 
International Shooting 
Sport Federation 
International Skating  
Union 
International Tennis  
Federation Limited 
The International Table 
Tennis Federation 
ICF 
IGF 
IHF 
IIHF 
IJF 
ISAF 
ISSF 
ISU 
ITF 
ITTF 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  Yes 
No 
Yes 
Southampton  UK 
Munich 
Lausanne 
London 
Lausanne 
Vancouver 
Budapest 
Aigle 
Monaco 
Corsier‐sur‐
Vevey 
Lausanne 
Dublin 
Seoul 
Germany 
Switzerland  Yes 
UK 
No 
Switzerland  Yes 
Canada 
Hungary 
Yes
8
 
No 
The International Triathlon  ITU 
Union 
International Weightlifting  IWF 
Federation 
Union Cycliste  
Internationale 
Union International de 
Pentathlon Moderne 
United World Wrestling 
World Curling Federation 
World Rugby 
World Taekwondo  
Federation 
UCI 
UIPM 
UWW 
WCF 
WR 
WTF 
Switzerland  No 
Monaco 
Yes 
Switzerland  No 
Switzerland  Yes 
Ireland 
Korea 
Yes 
Yes 
8
In the case of the ITU, an official offered to assist with the data gathering.
Play the Game
24
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0025.png
3.2 Data collection 
The study relies on the
raw
data collected within the framework of the Sports Governance
Observer survey (see Part III of this report).
4. Analysis 
This section applies the Principal-Agent model in order to analyse the institutional design
of ISFs. The decision-making bodies of ISFs are conceptualised as agents, who fulfil a range
of tasks on behalf of three main groups of principals, namely national sports federations,
athletes, and national public authorities. If ISFs do not have an institutional design
implemented that allows principals to monitoring and sanction decision-making body
members, the likelihood that the organisations demonstrate slack is high.
4.1 Delegation of authority to ISFs 
ISFs fulfil a range of tasks on behalf of a diverse group of principals (Geeraert and
Drieskens, 2015a). This section identifies three groups of principals, which function as ISFs’
main constituents: national sports federations, athletes, and national public authorities (see
Figure 1). The reason for focusing on these principals is that, in general, ISFs mostly fulfil
tasks on their behalf. True, the actual level of representation of these principals varies
between ISFs. Certain ISFs even fulfil very important tasks on behalf of other principals
(such as clubs) (Geeraert, 2016a).
9
Yet when analysing ISFs as a group, this study argues
and assumes that national sports federations, athletes, and national public authorities are
the most prominent principals.
Figure 2. Delegation of authority to ISFs by principals 
Athletes
Clubs
National
sports federations
ISFs
National
public authorities
General public
ISFs fulfil tasks and, therefore, act as agents for three main groups of actors: national sports
federations, athletes, and national public authorities:
Firstly,
national sports federations
have initially ceded sovereignty to ISFs to facilitate
international competition and to ensure clear and consistent sports rules across federations.
They explicitly delegated tasks to ISFs; thus, this relationship is closest to a Principal-Agent
relationship in the traditional sense (Geeraert and Drieskens, 2015a). Because they created
Note that EU institutions can also be conceptualised as principals of ISFs (Geeraert and Drieskens, 2015;
Geeraert, 2016). Focus here, however, does not dwell on EU control of ISFs.
9
Play the Game
25
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
ISFs, they enshrined into their statutes control options such as election procedures, report-
reporting requirements, and so on. The main way in which national federations can control
ISFs is through these statutory options for control. National federations are therefore – in
principle – the most powerful principals of ISFs: other principals lack statutory options for
controlling ISFs.
Importantly, national federations are not always inclined to control their ISFs’ decision-
making bodies. The reason is that senior sports officials have means at their disposal to
manipulate the preferences of member federations, such as awarding funding or the
privilege of hosting sporting events (Sugden and Tomlinson, 1998, pp. 144-151; Schenk,
2011; Forster and Pope, 2004). National federations may thus become rather benevolent in
order to be able to receive such benefits. This underscores the importance of institutional
design: firstly, robust control mechanisms can mitigate the issue; and secondly, the
institutional design of ISFs may allow other principals to monitor ISFs’ decision-making
bodies.
Secondly,
ISFs also act on behalf of sports stakeholders such as
athletes
and
clubs:
they
devise rules and policies, which athletes and clubs must abide by. These principals are
formally linked to an ISF through a chain of delegation: individual athletes form clubs,
clubs form national sports federations to organise competition, and national sports
federations create continental and international sports federations. In this chain, in
principle, only the principals closest to ISFs, national sports federations, hold statutory
options for control. They are the
proximate principals
(Nielson and Tierney, 2003, p. 249).
This means that especially athletes are put in a complicated position regarding control.
Even though ISFs are increasingly regulating their profession, athletes seem to lack direct
control options over their principals. In order to control their ISFs, they need to voice their
grievances to their club, their club then has to pass these on to its national federation, and
the national federation has to contact the ISF. Consequently, in order for athletes to control
ISFs, there must be almost perfect control in each link of the delegation chain. This is rather
unrealistic: according to Nielson and Tierney, “agency slack increases as the delegation
chain grows longer” because some degree of slack is likely to occur in each link in the
delegation chain (Nielson and Tierney, 2003, p. 249). This is problematical, because athletes
can be conceptualised as
ultimate principals:
the chain of delegation emerged from their
initial delegation and is therefore ultimately intended to facilitate athletes’ competition.
Thirdly,
as sports commercialised and globalised,
national public authorities
(and, by
extension, the general public) have become increasingly important principals (Geeraert,
2016b). In short, public authorities demonstrate a tacit or explicit tolerance of ISFs’
regulation and policy-making on their behalf (cf. Héritier and Lehmkuhl, 2008, p. 5).
Firstly, national public authorities constitute a part of a chain of delegation that links to
ISFs. In certain countries, public authorities explicitly and formally delegate the task of
regulating national-level sport to national sports federations (Vocasport, 2004, p. 53). In
Play the Game
26
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0027.png
other countries, delegation to national sports federations is more informal in nature.
10
Since
national federations are part of a system controlled by ISFs, public authorities also
implicitly delegate authority to these organisations. Secondly, delegation from national
public authorities to ISFs also takes place directly. States (implicitly) delegate legislative
powers to sports bodies, including, for instance, important parts of employment rules for
athletes (Geeraert and Drieskens, 2015a, p. 1451). Moreover, although national sports
federations are the official candidates, national governments
de facto
take part in the
bidding race for the organisation of international sports events and invest significant
resources to prepare candidacy (Walters, 2011). ISFs, then, perform the task of selecting a
suitable host on their behalf.
Regulatory norm production within ISFs, however, operates with such great autonomy
from public authorities that it is not realistic “to assert that the agents work under the
control or supervision of a national constitutional principal in any meaningful hierarchical
sense” (Lindseth, 2004, p. 4). As depicted in Figure 1, most ISFs are based in Switzerland,
where they have so far benefitted from a quasi-unregulated system.
Figure 3: Host countries of the 35 Olympic ISFs 
3
9
23
Switzerland
Other European country
Outside Europe
The Swiss Civil Code provides only very basic minimum requirements for associations,
while the overall Swiss legal framework allows for large degrees of both fiscal and
organisational autonomy and limited prosecution of private corruption. Recently
introduced amendments to the Unfair Competition Act and the Swiss Criminal Code make
corruption in international sports organisations a criminal offence, and Swiss authorities
can actively prosecute offenses on the condition that there is a public interest. These
amendments were introduced specifically in response to recent FIFA corruption scandals.
The Swiss government initially suggested stricter amendments. Following lobbying by the
private sector, which would equally be affected by the law, the amendments were toned
down to include the condition of public interest. Other national public authorities are
Granted, some (neoliberal) states have no interest in regulating sport. This does not imply, however, that
there has been no delegation of (regulatory) tasks. Here, delegation to national federations is implicit and
informal in nature. That delegation nevertheless does take place is evidenced by the fact that national
public authorities can, in principle, overrule national federations and even take over the regulation of
sport.
10
Play the Game
27
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0028.png
generally faced with regulatory overstretch in relation to ISFs: they do not hold statutory
options for control.
In what follows,
the institutional design
of the 35 Olympic sports federations is analysed.
Focus here is on the presence of formal control mechanisms, which prevent ISF officials
from pursuing their own interests at the expense of their principals.
11
More specifically, the
presense of five distinct organisational arrangements that allow for monitoring and
sanctioning ISFs are explored, namely (1)
screening and selection mechanisms,
(2)
monitoring
and reporting requirements,
(3)
administrative procedures,
(4)
institutional checks,
and (5)
elections
(Calvert, McCubbins and Weingast, 1989; Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991; Pollack,
1997; Fearon, 1999). It must be noted that most of these mechanisms are intended to enable
national sports federations to control ISFs. This is logical, given that these actors have
created ISFs and function as
proximate principals.
In fact, it would even be rather impractical
to formally allow too many actors to control ISFs (cf. Nielson and Tierney, 2003).
Nonetheless, as will be demonstrated, the institutional design of ISFs may also allow public
authorities, the public in general, athletes and other stakeholders to control these
organisations, thereby mitigating the likelihood of slack.
4.2 Screening and selection mechanisms – main findings 
Before contracting agents, principals can engage in screening processes; these processes
reduce information asymmetries about agents’ preferences and capabilities. They allow
principals to “sort out good agents from bad ones” (Strøm, 2000, p. 271). Appointing agents
with preferences that do not diverge from those of the principals decreases the likelihood
of slack because agents will have fewer motives to act opportunistically. It is necessary that
screening processes take place on the basis of both professional criteria, ensuring that the
agent is capable of performing the delegated tasks, and integrity criteria, ensuring that
he/she does not have unethical motives. It is of course nearly impossible to fully observe
the agent’s preferences and characteristics. Yet installing robust screening and selection
mechanisms increases the likelihood that the right persons are appointed at the outset.
The survey indicates that the vast majority of ISFs lack adequate screening and selection
mechanisms:
In corporate governance, establishing a nominations committee to screen potential
candidates for executive functions is standard practice (Pass, 2004). Such
committees typically perform both professional and integrity checks, and they
include independent (external) experts (Independent Governance Committee,
2014). The survey shows that only four federations (11%) have a nominations
committee in place that performs integrity and professional checks.
Principals should have sufficient time to inform themselves about candidates
standing for election. It is therefore important that the candidates are announced in
11
Emphasis is therefore placed on formal rules and procedures implemented in the institutional design of
ISFs. It must be noted, however, that informal and even exogenous control options may be at the disposal
of principals (Calvert
et al.
1989: 606; Geeraert and Drieskens, 2015a)
Play the Game
28
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
good time. However, a majority of 19 federations (54%) announce the candidates
standing for election one month or less before the elections take place. 32
federations (91%) announce candidates standing for elections less than 2 months
before they take place.
A lack of information about candidates’ policy intentions can be resolved by
obliging candidates to present their programme. In only one federation (ITU),
candidates are obliged to provide their manifesto.
4.3 Monitoring and reporting requirements – main findings 
As mentioned, principals can decrease information asymmetries concerning actions and
interests by monitoring agents’ actions. Consequently, agents will be motivated to act in
their principals’ best interest. Both (democratic) governments and private companies
usually have the statutory obligation to provide their principals reports on aspects of their
activities (Saalfeld, 2000; Pass, 2004). Such monitoring and reporting requirements oblige
agents to report on progress at predefined stages (cf. Mccubbins, Noll and Weingast, 1989).
The monitoring and reporting requirements implemented in ISFs’ institutional design are
mostly intended to inform national sports federations because these actors function as
proximate principals
(see above). However, a wider reporting may enable interested third
parties, such as athletes, clubs, NGOs, citizens, interest groups or other actors to examine
the actions of ISFs (McCubbins and Schwartz, 1984). Consequently, it not only enables
principals to rely on third parties to alert them to agency transgressions; third party
monitoring also decreases slack because it decreases the likelihood that acting contrary to
the wishes of principals will go unnoticed.
The majority of ISFs do not report to the general public. Even though the majority of
federations report to their member federations, the quality of reporting is lacking in a large
number of federations:
As they gather ISFs’ proximate principals, general assemblies have a very
important monitoring function (cf. Strøm, 2000). They should convene regularly –
the corporate governance standard is once a year – in order to review annual
reports. The general assemblies of 18 federations (51%) meet once a year, while
there are clear procedures enshrined in the statutes for convening emergency and
special meetings. Regarding 17 federations (49%), however, the general assemblies
meet once every two years or less.
Regarding the publication of important governing documents, all ISFs were found
to publish their statutes/constitution and sports rules (i.e., the rules of the game
and competition rules, such as the setting of the duration of a world championship
or the qualification rules for athletes).
Only eight federations (23%) publish the agenda and minutes of its general
assembly on their website. Yet 26 other federations (74%) provide these documents
to their member federations.
Play the Game
29
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Only four federations (11%) publish governing body decisions on their website and
(sometimes) explain the rationale behind key decisions.
Only three (9%) federations publish basic biographical information on their
governing body members that includes at least six of the following items: date of
birth, position in the organisation, nationality education, professional background,
tasks within the organisation, and activities in other sport organisations.
Furthermore, 26 federations (74%) publish biographical information that cover
three to five of these items.
Only six federations (17%) publish annual general activity reports on their websites
that include information on assets, accounts, revenue, sponsoring, and events. 15
federations (43%) are known to distribute a general activity report to their member
federations. The rest of the federations (14 or 40%) either do not provide a complete
and founded report to their member federations or no evidence of such a report
could be found.
Only eight federations (23%) publish (basic) reports of their standing committees
online. Five other federations (14%) provide basic reports of a part of their standing
committees. The majority of federations, 22 federations (63%) to be specific, do not
publish any reports on standing committees.
None of the federations publishes reports on remuneration, including per diem
payments and bonuses, of its board members and senior officials.
Only one federation (FIFA) publishes a detailed report of their major event online.
A minority of 12 federations (35%) publishes externally audited annual financial
reports on its website. A total of 22 federations (63%) have been found to provide
externally audited annual financial reports to their member federations.
Out of 19 federations for which data was available, seven federations (37%) allow
the media to participate and record at their general assembly meetings.
4.4 Administrative procedures – main findings 
Administrative procedures constitute the procedures agents must follow when executing
their tasks (McCubbins, Noll and Weingast, 1989). More specifically, they lay down the
steps agents must follow when conducting their tasks and, thus, limit the agents’ actions
a
priori.
By establishing administrative procedures, principals control agents without
investing too much resources. Next to procedural requirements, administrative procedures
may also involve enfranchising principals in the decision-making process, which assures
that agents are responsive to their interests.
The survey shows that the majority of ISFs do not have adequate administrative
procedures in place:
Play the Game
30
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
A quorum (i.e., a minimum number of attendees required to conduct business and
to cast votes) prevents that a small group of actors is able to monopolise power. No
federation has both a quorum installed at (at least) 50% for the legislative body and
one at 75% for the decision-making body. Ten federations (29%) have a quorum in
place in both their legislative and decision-making bodies, with the quorum for the
legislative body set at a minimum of 50%. Six federations (17%) have no quorum
installed for either their legislative or decision-making body.
Research suggests that governing body activity, measured by meeting frequency, is
an important dimension of board operations (Vafeas, 1999). Governing bodies that
meet frequently are more likely to perform their duties diligently and in accordance
with principals’ interests (Lipton and Lorsch, 1992). In only four federations out of
29 federations for which data was available (14%), the governing bodies meet
quarterly at the least. In seven federations (20%), the governing body meets once a
year or less. In seven other federations (20%), the governing body meets more
frequently than once a year, but less or equal to once every six months.
A code of ethics
defines unacceptable behaviour within an organisation. It
constitutes a set of rules that limits the autonomy of agents to behaviour that is
deemed ethical. Put differently, a code of ethics aims to limit slack in the form of
unethical behaviour. For the 32 federations for which data was available, a majority
of 18 federations (56%) was found to have a code of ethics that includes crucial
components such as the prohibition of bribery and procedures covering the offer or
receipt of gifts. Seven federations (22%) do not make any reference to a code of
ethics in their governing documents or on their websites.
Conflicts of interest rules impose the notification and disclosure of conflicting
interests and, in certain cases, mandatory recusal from decisions. Conflicts of
interest may arise in particular in certain high-risk areas relating to ISFs. For
instance, governing body members may directly benefit from the choice of the
organisation of events, commercial deals or the distribution of funds to member
federations (Pieth, 2011, p. 30). A minority of six (17%) federations have clear
conflict of interest rules in place that include disclosure requirements and the duty
to abstain from voting in particular cases, and define appropriate thresholds. Seven
(20%) federations do not have conflict of interest rules in place at all.
The allocation of major events constitutes a high-risk area for ISFs in relation to
corruption. Allowing agents to make hosting decisions has proven to lead to
corruption and the concentration of power in the past. Moreover, when hoping to
secure the hosting of an event, member federations (principals) will be less inclined
to hold their agents to account. Even though corruption is not ruled out in this case,
an important step towards improving the allocation process of major events is by
allowing member federations to vote on the appropriate host. In 18 of the 29
federations for which data was available (62%), the governing body selects the host.
Importantly, in none of the federations, the selection of host candidates takes place
Play the Game
31
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
according to a transparent and objectively reproducible process, in which bidding
dossiers are reviewed independently and assigned a score on the basis of pre-
established criteria.
An overwhelming majority of 34 ISFs have responded to athletes’ lack of control
options by formally granting athlete representatives consultative status in their
organisational structures. Yet in order to enable monitoring senior officials’
conduct, athletes’ representatives should have access to decision-making (cf.
Arnstein, 1969; Woods, 1999; Young, 2000). In addition, there must be a clear
connection between the representatives and the athletes, which can be achieved by
having athletes elected by their peers (Fearon, 1999; Saward, 2005). In a majority of
23 federations (66%), the chairman/woman of the athletes’ commission is a
member of the decision-making body. However, in only eight federations (23%),
athletes elect the chairman/woman of the athletes’ commission. In eight other
federations (23%), the chairman/woman of the athletes’ commission is elected by
the congress.
4.5 Institutional checks – main findings 
Principals can also install institutional checks. This control mechanism hinges on the fact
that an agent is established and charged with monitoring the activities of another agent and
sometimes holds veto power (Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991, pp. 33-34). Institutional checks
are usually employed in order to prevent embezzlements, insider trading, corruption, and
abuse and concentration of power. Yet in order for institutional checks to work effectively,
they must have the authority to veto or block the actions of the agent and be independent
from the agent (Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991, pp. 33-34). Examples of such checks are
internal and external audits and ethics committees (Banks, 1989; Weber, 1993).
The majority of federations do not have robust institutional checks in place:
Ethics committees monitor compliance with the principles in the ethics code. They
head investigations upon receiving reports of violations. Only when a robust ethics
committee is in place does a code of ethics have a positive impact on ethical
behaviour (Weber 1993, p. 430). 12 federations (34%) do not have an ethics
committee in place. Moreover, in only five federations (14%), the ethics committee
is robust, meaning that it is independent from the governing body and has the
power to initiate proceedings on its own initiative.
An external audit is usually conducted by an organisation independent from the
organisation that is being audited. External audits scrutinize annual financial
accounts and examine and assess risks associated with finance. A vast majority of
33 federations (94%) is externally audited according to internationally recognised
standards
Supplemental to external audit, the internal audit provides external auditors with
business, activity and process knowledge, and inform them on the risks facing the
organisation. In addition, the internal audit assesses the quality of the internal
Play the Game
32
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
control system, including risk management (IIA, 2013). An internal audit commit-
committee usually provides oversight to the internal audit. Only six federations
(17%) have an internal audit committee that has a clearly defined role and has the
authority to oversee the internal audit and assesses the quality of the internal
control system.
A minority of eight federations (23%) have an independent committee in place that
allows national federations, club, players, or official directly affected by a decision-
making body decision to appeal that decision.
4.6 Elections – main findings 
Elections provide an important incentive for agents to behave according to their principals’
interests (Calvert, McCubbins and Weingast, 1989, p. 602; Fearon, 1999; Pollack, 2003, p.
108). The credible threat of being replaced by a challenger in case of slack incentivizes
agents to conform to their principals’ wishes and to refrain from opportunistic behaviour
(Barro 1973; Ferejohn 1986; Besley and Case, 1995). Moreover, elections offer principals the
possibility to “weed out bad types and retain good types” (Alt, Bueno de Mesquita and
Rose, 2011, p. 171); thus selectively retaining ‘good’ agents (Smart and Sturm, 2013, p. 93).
In a vast majority of 24 federations (69%), all decision-making body members,
including the president, are elected. In 23 federations (66%), elections take place
according to clear and objective procedures (i.e., procedures that cover information
on people qualified to vote; majority or percentage needed to win the election and,
where applicable, weighting of votes; quorum; and election rounds) and secret
ballots are used. Secret ballots prevent retaliation by elected decision-making body
members against member federations that did not vote for them. When anticipating
retaliation, member federations’ voting may be influenced.
An important issue regarding voting is the presence of term limits, namely a restriction on
the number of terms an incumbent may serve. At first sight, term limits are difficult to
reconcile with the logics of the Principal-Agent model. After all, principals cannot retain
good agents for a period longer than the restricted period. Most importantly, however,
incumbents in their final term no longer operate under the threat of being replaced: they
are forced to retire anyway. In the absence of this threat, they are, in principle, no longer
incentivised to act in accordance with their principals’ wishes (Cohen and Spitzer, 1992;
Alt, Bueno de Mesquita and Rose, 2011). Why, then, would an ISF impose term limits?
Even though imposing term limits seems counterintuitive, there are a number of good
reasons for doing so, certainly within the context of sports governance.
Firstly, incumbents hold manifold advantages over challengers and are therefore more
likely to be re-elected (Tabarrok, 1994). Such incumbency advantages are often cumulative
(they grow with years of service) and include access to resources, fear of the uncertainty
associated with electing an alternative candidate with voters, name recognition, overall
power, and seniority (Cohen and Spitzer, 1992, p. 479; Cain and Levin, 1999, pp. 174-179;
Tabarrok, 1994, p. 344). Seniority produces incumbency advantage – with seniority comes
Play the Game
33
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
power, which can be deployed to be re-elected, but also constitutes an advantage in itself.
In the case that continental sports federations elect governing body members, they will be
inclined to vote for incumbents because they have more experience. Voters reason that they
therefore have more power in the international federation’s governing body and that
electing an alternative candidate will give them a comparative disadvantage in relation to
other continental federations (cf. Tabarrok, 1994, p. 344). Altogether, the incumbency
advantage leads to high rates of re-election. Geeraert, Alm and Groll (2014b, p. 300)
provide evidence for this thesis in relation to the past presidents of the 35 Olympic ISFs.
They demonstrate how 60% of the presidents had been in office for more than eight years
on average. Why are long tenures problematical for ISF presidents and senior officials?
When re-election becomes more likely, even a certainty, agents will no longer be
incentivised to act in their principals’ best interest since the threat of being replaced by a
challenger no longer looms (Cohen and Spitzer, 1992, p. 480; Tabarrok, 1994, p. 334).
Moreover, certain re-elections result in apathetic voters and, thus, principals that are no
longer incentivised to hold agents to account (Cohen and Spitzer, 1992, p. 480).
Secondly, term limits prevent slack in the form of accumulation, concentration and abuse
of power. Incumbents are able to accumulate power over the years they spend in office
(Cohen and Spitzer, 1992, p. 479). They may even be tempted to abuse this power through
covert activity in order to stay in office (Beerman, 2011, p. 1116-1117).
Thirdly, incumbents are more likely to target voters who benefit the most from their
policies and therefore risk favouritism of a group of principals (Tabarrok, 1994, p. 345;
Maltz, 2007, p. 131). This is particularly problematic in international sports governance,
where, given their global scope, ISFs’ members constitute a very heterogeneous group.
Continuously targeting and favouring a particular section of this group may result in a
guaranteed re-election – indeed, even bad agents can be difficult to replace in the absence
of term limits. The most blatant example of such a practice can be found within FIFA,
where a sort of ‘patronage system’ existed in which “[f]riends received personal favors or
were able to raise funds for their national associations, their confederations or their local
infrastructure in exchange for support for their benefactor” (Pieth, 2014b, p. 8). Surely,
alternation prevents such a system from developing (Tabarrok, 1994, p. 345; Maltz, 2007, p.
131). Term limits even induce agents to act in the general interest instead of favouring a
particular group of principals (Tabarrok, 1994, p. 344; Glazer and Wattenberg, 1996; Smart
and Sturm, 2013)
Fourthly, term limits provide for more diversity among agents because they allow for new
(historically underrepresented) types of people to be elected to office (Cain and Levin, p.
175-176; Tabarrok, 1994, p. 335). Term limits therefore contribute to a solution for the
underrepresentation of, for instance, women in ISF governing bodies (Geeraert et al., 2014b,
298-299).
Fifthly, term limits enable fresh ideas for solving problems to enter the organisation (Cohen
and Spitzer, 1992, pp. 480-481). They therefore constitute a remedy for the perceived inertia
in international sports governance (Katwala, 2000).
Play the Game
34
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
None of the federations has rules in place that limit the terms of office of the
president to two terms of four years and governing body members to two terms of
four years. However, 11 federations (31%) have some form of limitation in place.
Yet they apply only for either the president or the governing body members or the
limitation allows the president or the governing body members to stay in office for
a (consecutive) period of more than eight years or limitations are in place for a
number of consecutive terms only.
5. Conclusion 
This study confirmed the hypothesis that the institutional design of ISFs is generally
flawed. By relying on the Principal-Agent model, the analysis demonstrated that the
majority of the 35 Olympic ISFs do not have an institutional design implemented that
allows principals to monitor and sanction decision-making body members. Therefore,
senior sports officials are not sufficiently incentivised to act in accordance with their
principals’ interests.
Firstly, as proximate principals, member federations hold the most statutory options for
controlling ISFs’ decision-making bodies compared to national public authorities and
athletes. Yet these controls are not on a sufficiently high level. The vast majority of ISFs
lacks solid screening and selection mechanisms, monitoring and reporting requirements,
administrative procedures, institutional checks, and elections. Moreover, national sports
federations have been known to become rather benevolent in order not to miss out benefits
such as funding and the privilege of hosting important events. This problem is reinforced
in the absence of adequate control mechanisms.
Secondly, the position of athletes within ISFs’ structures needs to be enhanced. Athletes’
position in sports governance has been complicated by the fact that they are linked to ISFs
through clubs and national federations. ISFs have made efforts to involve athletes in
consultative committees, yet administrative procedures need to be installed that allow
athletes to be included in decision-making. Furthermore, institutional checks should be
installed that allow athletes to contest decisions by the decision-making body. Only then
will athletes be able to effectively monitor ISFs.
Thirdly, in order to ensure that ISFs’ decision-making bodies act in the general interest, the
quality of institutional checks needs to be enhanced so that unethical behaviour is
prevented. In addition, term limits need to be installed and reporting requirements need to
be implemented that oblige the publication of important reports and information so that
third parties such as NGOs, news media, and representative organisations of sports
stakeholders can monitor ISFs on behalf of ISFs’ principals.
Enhancing the institutional design of ISFs allows for the calibration of ISFs’ actions with the
normative expectations of principals. Only then will ISFs adequately address the legitimacy
gaps they are confronted with, and only then will they be able to fulfil their pivotal role in
international sports governance.
Play the Game
35
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Part III. Sports Governance Observer survey 
1. Introduction 
How can the institutional design or the governance of ISFs be improved? One of the
obstacles towards achieving better governance in ISFs is the lack of a generally accepted,
comprehensive and practical set of good governance indicators (Geeraert, 2015). The Sports
Governance Observer (SGO) aims to provide a modest step towards filling this void. More
specifically, it aims to inform ISFs on how they can organise their affairs in a sustainable
and effective manner as well as monitor their governance practices. The SGO is an easy to
use benchmarking tool based on composite indicators that can be used to assess good
governance in ISFs. The tool is based on a checklist of good governance indicators that was
developed by the AGGIS group (2013), which is further elaborated in this section by means
of a scoring system. Importantly, the Sports Governance Observer is based on
basic
indicators for good governance. A thorough assessment of good governance practices in
ISFs requires an in-depth study on a case-by-case basis.
Through its scoring system, the Sports Governance Observer functions as a tool for self-
assessment as well as external benchmarking. This is facilitated by a comprehensive
methodological sheet, designed for each individual indicator, which includes clear
requirements for each scoring category as well as an explanation of the importance of the
relevant indicator.
The final part of this report continues as follows. The second section presents the
methodology behind the Sports Governance Observer, which allows for the construction of
an SGO index as a measure of good governance. The third section introduces the
methodological sheets of the Sports Governance Observer, which include the scoring
system as well as explanations of the importance of each individual indicator. The fourth
and final section shows the results of the application of the Sports Governance Observer to
the 35 Olympic ISFs.
2. Methodology 
2.1 Constructing the SGO index  
To capture its empirical complexity, it is necessary to break down the notion of good
governance, measure its components and aggregate them (Nardo, Saisana, Saltelli &
Tarantola, 2005). The Sports Governance Observer is comprised out of four composite
indicators (dimensions), namely
transparency, democracy, checks and balances
and
solidarity
(see below).
Each dimension is a combination of individual indicators (36 in total) that represent
different dimensions of the respective composite indicator. Each of the 36 individual
indicators is quantified by using a pre-established scoring system (ranging from 1 for ‘not
fulfilled at all’ to 5 for ‘state of the art’). Especially large federations should be expected to
score 4-5 on a given indicator. The individual indicators were selected and quantified
Play the Game
36
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0037.png
under a
fit-for-purpose
principle and, thus, on the basis of a thorough review of academic
(management, political science and (sports) governance) literature. Importantly, focus here
is mostly on rules-based or
de jure
rather than outcome-based or
de facto
indicators of good
governance (see Kaufmann and Kraay, 2008).
12
The indicators were subsequently applied to the 35 Olympic ISFs. This allowed for con-
structing an
SGO index
for each of the 35 federations according to the following formula:
12
10
4
4
7
7
1
100
This formula results in a
percentage score
that represents the average of the percentage
scores from the four governance dimensions (transparency, democracy, checks and balanc-
es and solidarity) and the underlying 36 individual governance indicators.
In other words, the SGO index indicates to what degree the federations comply with the 36
indicators constituted in the four governance dimensions. Consequently, a federation get-
ting the highest possible score (5) on all included indicators in this survey would achieve
an SGO index of 100%.
The SGO index of the 35 federations combined is calculated according to the following
basic formula that gives the average percentage score of all federations:
35
The decision was made not to assign weights to the individual indicators on the basis of
their relative importance. Hopkins asserts: “[s]ince it is probably impossible to obtain
agreement on weights, the simplest arrangement [equal weighting] is the best choice”
(Hopkins, 1991, p. 1471). It must be noted that this stance has been contested (Cherchye,
Moesen, Rogge and Van Puyenbroeck, 2006). Yet for the sake of simplicity, and in order to
avoid methodological obstacles related to missing data, the SGO index is based on equal
weighting.
Despite their increasing use, composite indicators are the subjects of controversy. Of par-
ticular concern is “the inescapable subjectivity involved in their construction” (Cherchye,
Moesen, Rogge and Van Puyenbroeck, 2006, p. 111). This study acknowledges this issue
but seeks to mitigate it by opting for full transparency with regard to the scoring system of
the Sports Governance Observer.
12
Note that outcomes may differ from rules.
Play the Game
37
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
2.2 Data collection and analysis 
Data collection took place during 2014 and the first part of 2015. It focused on obtaining
basic data on the organisational structures and arrangements of the 35 ISFs in order to as-
sign scores to each of the 36 indicators of the Sports Governance Observer. The main data
sources were therefore the federations’ statutes, byelaws, internal regulations (if available)
and website. In addition, the Secretaries-General of the 35 federations were contacted by
means of a total of one letter and three e-mails with the question to review and supplement
the collected data. This process proved difficult, as the majority of federations were either
unresponsive or uncooperative. The response rate was 43%, with 15 federations providing
their comments and amendments.
One federation (AIBA) specifically declined to cooperate, 19 federations did not respond to
our request (see Table 1). Importantly, the federations were asked to review the unpro-
cessed data in the form of a questionnaire; they did not have the opportunity to scrutinise
their scores on each indicator. The final scoring based on the quantified indicators was thus
conducted without input from the federations.
The decision was made to omit the data on internal controls (indicator 3.3) from the analy-
sis because it was deemed unreliable. In the end, data was gathered for 1,064 of the 1,260
indicators (84%). Because of the large quantity of missing data for the fourth dimension
(38%), the decision was made to exclude the dimension from the calculation of the SGO
index for a federation when a threshold of 5/7 of fulfilled indicators for the dimension is
not reached. Consequently, the solidarity dimension is excluded for 17 federations.
3. The four dimensions of the Sports Governance Observer 
The good governance indicators of the sports governance observers are dispersed over four
dimensions, namely transparency, democratic processes, checks & balances, and solidarity.
Transparency
pertains the “degree of openness in conveying information” (Ball, 2009, p.
297). It is widely regarded as a panacea for good governance and failures of governance are
often linked to a lack of transparency (OECD, 2004, p. 50; Hood and Heald, 2006). Trans-
parency allows external actors to monitor the workings of an organisation and therefore
decrease the likelihood of opportunistic behaviour.
Democratic processes
concern rules and norms inherent to a democratic grammar of conduct
(Mouffe, 1993). In particular, they refer to participation in policy processes by those who
are affected by the policy (Arnstein, 1969; Pateman, 1970). Democratic processes increase
the accountability and effectiveness of organisations (Calvert, McCubbins and Weingast,
1989; Fearon, 1999; Klijn and Koppenjan, 2004).
Checks & balances
or mutual control procedures are paramount to prevent the concentration
of power in and they ensure that decision-making is robust, independent and free from
improper influence. They ensure that no senior official or department has absolute control
over decisions, and clearly define the assigned duties (Aucoin and Heintzman, 2000).
Play the Game
38
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Solidarity
refers to expressing responsibility towards internal and external stakeholders.
This involves practices relating to contributing to a better society and a cleaner environ-
ment by integrating social and environmental concerns in operations and interactions with
stakeholders.
In what follows, the dimensions, indicators and scoring system of the Sports Governance
Observer are presented.
 
Play the Game
39
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0040.png
3.1 Dimension 1. TRANSPARENCY AND PUBLIC COMMUNICATION 
Indicator 1.1  
The organisation publishes its statutes/constitution; byelaws; sport rules; organisational chart; and stra‐
tegic objectives on its website 
Explanation
Making these documents available online is a crucial first step in order to ensure that the
inner workings of an international sports federation (ISF) are open to public and stakehold-
er scrutiny. Firstly, statutes constitute a set of fundamental principles according to which
an organisation is governed. Secondly, byelaws are the rules that govern the internal man-
agement of an organisation. Thirdly, sports rules encompass sport rules
sensu stricto
– i.e.,
the rules of the game – and competition rules, such as the setting of the duration of a world
championship or the qualification rules for athletes. Fourthly, an organisational chart is a
diagram that shows the structure of an organisation, including the relationships between
and the relative ranks of its parts and positions. Finally, strategy formulation comprises the
task of analysing an organisation’s externals and internal environment and then selecting
appropriate strategies.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
Conditions 
None of the mentioned documents are available on the organisation’s 
website and  
The organisation publishes only one or two of the mentioned documents 
The organisation publishes only one or two of the mentioned docu‐
ments, but provides its internal stakeholders (member federations, 
athletes, clubs,…) other documents (making a total of at least four 
documents) through newsletters or via a protected member section 
of the organisation’s website 
The organisation publishes only three of the mentioned documents, 
including the statutes  
The organisation publishes four of the mentioned documents includ‐
ing the statutes and the organisational chart but they are not re‐
trievable through the home page (or sub‐levels of the home page 
accessible through the home page) of the website 
Or 
Or 
Good  
The organisation publishes at least four of the mentioned documents 
including the statutes and they are retrievable through the home page 
(or sub‐levels of the home page accessible through the home page) of 
the website 
The organisation publishes all of the mentioned documents and they are 
retrievable through the home page (or sub‐levels of the home page ac‐
cessible through the home page) of the website 
State of the art 
Play the Game
40
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0041.png
Indicator 1.2  
The organisation publishes the agenda and minutes of its general assembly on its website 
Explanation
Publishing the agenda and minutes of statutory meetings allows for public scrutiny of the
relationship between senior sports officials and member federations. Minutes consist of a
record or summary of all motions, proposals, resolutions and any other matter formally
voted upon (including the vote thereon).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
 
 Conditions 
Not available on the organisation’s website 
Little information is published (e.g. only the agenda)  
The agenda and minutes are published, but they are not timely pub‐
lished (e.g. no minutes from recent statutory meeting)  
Incomplete (they do not reflect all the discussed items, participation 
rate, etc.),  
not objective  
not understandable 
The agenda and minutes are provided to the organisation’s internal 
stakeholders (member federations, athletes, clubs,…) through newslet‐
ters or via a protected member section of the organisation’s website. 
They are timely provided, complete (they reflect all the discussed items, 
participation rate, etc.), objective and understandable  
OR two or more of the following: 
or 
Good 
The agenda and minutes are published, but they are either 
Incomplete (they do not include all the discussed items, participation 
rate, etc.),  
not objective  
not understandable 
not timely published 
State of the art 
The agenda and minutes, timely published on the organisation’s website, are 
complete (they reflect all the discussed items, participation rate, etc.), objec‐
tive and understandable 
Play the Game
41
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0042.png
Indicator 1.3 
The organisation publishes decisions taken at its executive body meetings on its website 
Explanation
By producing regular narrative accounts that seek to justify its decisions, actions and re-
sults in the eyes of its internal stakeholders and the general public, an ISF can prevent that
it becomes a closed and secret club (Fox and Miller, 1995; Dryzek, 2000; Newman, 2005).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 
 Conditions 
The organisation does not produce any information regarding its executive 
body meetings 
The organisation publishes summaries of its executive board’s decisions. The 
published information is one of the following: 
and 
Moderate 
the organisation does not explain the rationale behind any key decisions 
not timely published  
not complete (it does not reflect all the discussed items)  
not objective 
not understandable 
The organisation publishes summaries of its executive board’s decisions. The 
published information is one of the following: 
or 
Summaries of the organisation’s executive board’s decisions are provided to 
the organisation’s internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, 
clubs,…) through newsletters or via a protected member section of the or‐
ganisation’s website. They are timely provided, complete (they reflect all the 
discussed items, participation rate, etc.), objective and understandable 
not timely published  
not complete (it does not reflect all the discussed items)  
not objective 
not understandable 
it does not explain the rationale behind any key decisions.  
Good 
 
The organisation publishes summaries of its executive board’s decisions. The 
published information is 
timely published  
complete (it reflects all the discussed items)  
objective 
understandable 
The organisation explains the rationale behind certain key decisions. 
State of the art 
The organisation publishes summaries of its executive board’s decisions. The 
published information is 
timely published  
Play the Game
42
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0043.png
complete (it reflects all the discussed items)  
objective 
understandable 
The organisation explains the rationale behind all key decisions. 
Indicator 1.4 
The organisation gives the media access to its general assembly meetings 
Explanation
Allowing media access to statutory meetings enhances public scrutiny.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  Media access is not allowed 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
Media access is restricted and recording is not allowed 
Media access is restricted and recording is restricted 
Statutory meetings are open to media  
They are open to being photographed, broadcast, webcast or otherwise 
recorded and/or transmitted by audio or video means 
Statutory meetings are open to media 
They are open to being photographed, broadcast, webcast or otherwise 
recorded and/or transmitted by audio or video means 
Public notice of the time and place of a meeting scheduled is given to the 
news media. In addition, it is conspicuously posted on the organisation’s 
website 
State of the art 
Play the Game
43
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0044.png
Indicator 1.5 
The organisation publishes basic information about its board members and senior officials on its website 
Explanation
Basic biographical information gives the general public insight into senior officials’ back-
ground, affiliations and education.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  No information 
Weak 
Moderate 
The available information is extremely basic and/or is only available for a very 
small group of senior officials    
The information covers 3 or more but not all of the following items:  
date of birth 
or 
cover all of the items but is not available for all the senior officials 
position 
nationality 
education 
professional background  
tasks within the organisation  
current activities in other sports organisations 
official functions and political posts 
Good 
State of the art 
The published information includes at least six of the items listed above 
The published information includes all or more of the items listed above 
Play the Game
44
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0045.png
Indicator 1.6 
Contact details to board members and senior officials are published on the organisation’s website 
Explanation
The starting point of an accountability relationship is the ability to ask questions, so that
the actor that is being held accountable has to explain and justify his/her conduct (Bovens,
2007).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  No contact information 
Weak 
Only a general email address is available on the organisation’s website 
Details on how to reach the individual senior officials are not provided to 
the organisation’s internal stakeholders 
Moderate 
Details on how to reach the individual senior officials are provided to the or‐
ganisation’s internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, clubs,…) 
through newsletters or via a protected member section of the organisation’s 
website 
A general contact address for officials is available on the organisation’s 
website 
The email address and phone number of the secretariat is available on the 
organisation’s website 
Details on how to reach the individual senior officials are provided to the 
organisation’s internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, 
clubs,…) through newsletters or via a protected member section of the 
organisation’s website 
The email address and phone number of the secretariat is available on the 
organisation’s website 
Email addresses of individual senior officials are available on the organisa‐
tion’s website 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
45
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0046.png
Indicator 1.7 
The organisation publishes information about its member federations on its website 
Explanation
Publishing general information about member federations provides insight into the impact
of an ISF.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
Only two or less elements from score 5 are published or members are pre‐
sented without any additional information 
All elements from score 4 are provided to the organisation’s internal 
stakeholders (member federations, athletes, clubs,…) through newsletters 
or via a protected member section of the organisation’s website 
3 or more, but not all elements from score 4 are published 
Not fulfilled at all  No information is available 
or  
Good 
Information on the member federations includes: 
Founding year 
Affiliated since 
Website 
Email address 
Address 
President 
General secretary 
State of the art 
Information on the member federations includes: 
Founding year 
Affiliated since 
Website 
Email address 
Address 
President 
General secretary 
Nr of affiliated athletes 
Play the Game
46
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0047.png
Indicator 1.8 
The organisation publishes its annual general activity report on its website 
Explanation
Annual reports outline the organisation’s accomplishments. Therefore, they constitute a
vital element of accountability since they provide the general public with in-depth and
comprehensive information on the activities carried out by the ISF and its attained goals.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
 Conditions 
Or 
Or  
Moderate 
It is provided to the member federations, but it does not includes all ele‐
ments in score 4 
General activity report meets the conditions in score 4, but it is not pub‐
lished on an annual basis  
The most recent report is not available  
It is not easily accessible through the website and/or the annual reports 
from the previous 3 years are not available  
It includes all elements in score 4 but is not published online but provided 
to the organisation’s internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, 
clubs,…) through newsletters or via a protected member section of the 
organisation’s website 
It is not provided to the organisation’s internal stakeholders 
General activity report is published but does not meet all of the condi‐
tions in score 4  
Not fulfilled at all  No general reports are published 
And/or  
Or  
And/or  
Good 
State of the art 
General activity report is published online annually and includes complete and 
founded information on accounts, assets, revenue, sponsoring and events 
General activity report is published annually and includes complete, objective 
and understandable information on accounts, assets, events, revenue, spon‐
soring, development of the sport and programmes 
Play the Game
47
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0048.png
Indicator 1.9 
The organisation publishes reports of its standing committees on its website 
Explanation
Standing committees, such as finance, ethics and athlete committees, have an important
supporting function in the governance of ISFs. Publishing reports on their activities is
therefore an important part of reporting transparency.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
Annual reports of less than 50% of the standing committees are published 
online 
Or 
Reports of all standing committees are provided to the organisation’s 
internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, clubs,…) through 
newsletters or via a protected member section of the organisation’s web‐
site 
Reports meets the conditions in score 4, but they are not published on an 
annual basis  
The most recent report is not available  
It is not easily accessible through the website and/or the annual reports 
from the previous three years are not available 
Annual reports of  50% or more of the standing committees are published 
Not fulfilled at all  No reports are published 
Or 
and/or  
Good 
State of the art 
and/or  
Annual reports of 75% of the standing committees are published online 
Annual reports of all the standing committees are published online 
Play the Game
48
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0049.png
Indicator 1.10 
The organisation publishes an externally audited annual financial report on its website according to rec‐
ognised international standards
13
 
Explanation
A contemporary financial compliance system includes all financial transactions in an audit-
ed bookkeeping and financial reporting system and applies strict bookkeeping and audit-
ing standards. In order to make ISFs publicly accountable, this information should be made
available to the general public, especially since ISFs often operate under a large
de facto
autonomy.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Annual financial reports are published, but they are not externally audited
or 
Moderate 
Or 
Externally audited annual financial reports are provided to the organisa‐
tion’s internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, clubs,…) 
through newsletters or via a protected member section of the organisa‐
tion’s website and reports from the past 3 years are available 
The organisation publishes an externally audited annual financial report 
on its website according to recognised international standards, but the 
reports from the past 3 years are not all available 
Comprehensive information is published as part of general report 
Only basic financial information is published as part of a general report 
Externally audited financial reports according to recognised international 
standards are published, but the latest report is not available  
Not fulfilled at all  No financial reports are published 
Weak 
Good 
Or 
State of the art 
The organisation publishes an externally audited annual financial report on its 
website according to recognised international standards and the reports from 
the past 3 years are available 
13
E.g. International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS)
Play the Game
49
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0050.png
Indicator 1.11 
The organisation publishes regulations and reports on remuneration, including per diem payments and 
bonuses, of its board members and senior officials on its website 
Explanation
Senior sports officials have a responsibility to cautiously handle financial assets. A com-
mitment to developing sport, a public good, does not resonate well with personal enrich-
ment. However, personal enrichment is a particular risk associated with ISFs due to the
large degrees of autonomy under which senior sports officials operate.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
 Conditions 
Moderate 
Or 
Regulations and reports on remuneration are provided to the organisa‐
tion’s internal stakeholders (member federations, athletes, clubs,…) 
through newsletters or via a protected member section of the organisa‐
tion’s website and reports from the past 3 years are available 
Regulations are available 
Reports exist, but they are not available 
Regulations are available 
Reports are available 
Regulations are in place, but not available on the website 
No reports are available 
Regulations are available 
Reports on remuneration do not exist 
Not fulfilled at all  No information is published 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
50
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0051.png
Indicator 1.12 
The organisation publishes main event reports with detailed and relevant information on its website 
Explanation
Events are often the biggest source of revenue for ISFs and they can increase the popularity
of the sport across borders. They have the potential to have both positive and negative ef-
fects on the wider community. Since they cannot be organised without public support, they
must be open to close public scrutiny. Key elements of an event report include financial
information, media coverage, sponsors, infrastructure, attendance rates and athlete partici-
pation.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
The report only includes 1 or 2 of the elements mentioned below 
The report includes more than 2 of the elements mentioned below 
Or 
Event reports are provided to the organisation’s internal stakeholders 
(member federations, athletes, clubs,…) through newsletters or via a pro‐
tected member section of the organisation’s website 
Not fulfilled at all  No report is available 
Good 
The event report includes sections on  
Governance 
Revenue 
Sponsors 
Media coverage 
Infrastructure 
Attendance 
Athlete participation 
State of the art 
The event report includes sections on  
Governance 
Revenue 
Sponsors 
Media coverage 
Infrastructure 
Attendance 
Athlete participation 
And, an objective assessments of economic, social and environmental 
impacts 
 
Play the Game
51
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0052.png
3.2 Dimension 2. DEMOCRATIC PROCESS 
Indicator 2.1 
There are elections of the president and the governing bodies and, where appropriate, the standing 
committees 
Explanation
A principal way for constituents to hold office holders accountable is through elections.
Faced with the possibility of not being re-elected, incumbents will be inclined to act in the
best interest of those who hold voting power.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
 Conditions 
Or 
Or 
Moderate 
Good 
The president is not elected 
A portion of the governing body members are elected by the congress or 
by continental federations 
The president is elected 
The majority of governing body members (with the exception of the sec‐
retary general) are elected by the congress or by continental federations  
The governing body can co‐opt members whose appointment is not ap‐
proved by the congress 
The president is elected by the congress 
All the other governing body members (with the exception of the secre‐
tary general) are elected by the congress or by continental federations 
The president is elected by the congress 
All the other governing body members (with the exception of the secre‐
tary general) are elected by the congress or by continental federations 
A nomination committee is established. This committee receives nomina‐
tions and ensures checks relating to professional and integrity criteria on 
all candidates 
The president is elected 
A portion of the governing body members are elected by the congress or 
by continental federations  
The president can co‐opt members whose appointment is not approved 
by the congress 
Only the president is elected or the governing body members  
He/she subsequently appoints the other members of the governing body 
Not fulfilled at all  No elections are in place 
State of the art 
Play the Game
52
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0053.png
Indicator 2.2 
Elections are on the basis of secret ballots and clear procedures detailed in the organisation’s governing 
document/s 
Explanation
Elections on the basis of secret ballots ensure that no voter fears reprisals. Clear procedures
add to the objectivity of elections.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
No secret ballots 
Or 
Procedures are in place but they do not cover information on people 
qualified to vote; majority or percentage needed to win the election and, 
where applicable, weighting of votes; quorum; and election rounds 
No secret ballots 
Procedures are in place and they cover information on people qualified to 
vote; majority or percentage needed to win the election and, where ap‐
plicable, weighting of votes; quorum; and election rounds 
Secret ballots  (or, secret ballots can be requested) 
Procedures are in place and they cover information on people qualified to 
vote; majority or percentage needed to win the election and, where ap‐
plicable, weighting of votes; quorum; and election rounds 
Secret ballots 
Procedures are in place and they cover information on people qualified to 
vote; majority or percentage needed to win the election and, where ap‐
plicable, weighting of votes; quorum; and election rounds 
The procedures are controlled by a body within the organisation (e.g. 
nomination committee) 
Not fulfilled at all  No clear procedures and no secret ballots 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
53
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0054.png
Indicator 2.3 
The organisation offers to the candidates standing for election opportunities to present their pro‐
gramme/manifesto 
Explanation
In order to make an informed vote, it is important for voters to have a clear picture on can-
didates’ policy agenda, preferences and interests.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  The candidates standing for election do not have opportunities to present 
their programme/manifesto. They are not obliged to announce their candidacy 
before the election takes place 
Weak 
Moderate 
Candidates who wish to stand for election are obliged to announce their can‐
didacy in less than 4 months before the elections take place 
Candidates who wish to stand for election are not obliged to announce their 
candidacy in good time (announced less than 4 months before the election) 
and the congress is informed of their candidacy OR they are not obliged to 
present their programme/manifesto to the congress 
Candidates who wish to stand for election must announce their candidacy 
in good time, also to the congress (at least 4 months)  
They must present their programme/manifesto to the congress 
Candidates who wish to stand for election must announce their candidacy 
in good time, also to the congress (at least 4 months) 
They must present their programme/manifesto to the congress 
Contributions from private actors to the campaign of a presidential candi‐
date are forbidden; a system of campaign financing is in place which pro‐
vides officially announced candidates, which have sufficient backing by a 
number of member federation, with funding; this system is controlled by 
a nomination committee 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
54
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0055.png
Indicator 2.4 
The decisions on allocation of major events are made through a democratic, open, transparent and objec‐
tively reproducible process 
Explanation
The allocation of the hosting of major events constitutes a high-risk area in relation to cor-
ruption and conflicts of interest. Such risks can be managed by making the bidding process
democratic, objective, open and transparent.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Weak 
 Conditions 
Moderate 
And 
Good 
the final candidate is elected by the congress  
Clear conflict of interest rules are in place (those can be part of a general 
conflict of interest regulations, applicable not only to the allocation of 
events) 
The criteria for a bid for major events are communicated to its members 
in good time (min. 1 year before the event is awarded) 
The bidding dossiers are reviewed, evaluated and scores are assigned on 
the basis of pre‐established and objective criteria 
Only bids achieving a minimum score are shortlisted 
The governing body confirms the shortlist and the final candidate is elect‐
ed by the congress 
Clear conflict of interest rules are in place (those can be part of a general 
conflict of interest regulations, applicable not only to the allocation of 
events) 
The organisation adopts a geographical rotation policy 
The criteria for a bid for major events are communicated to its members 
in good time (min. 1 year before the event is awarded) 
The bidding dossiers are reviewed, evaluated and scores are assigned on 
the basis of pre‐established and objective criteria 
External procurement experts assist with this evaluation 
Only bids achieving a minimum score are shortlisted 
The governing body confirms the shortlist 
The final candidate is elected by the congress 
Only one or two of the criteria below are fulfilled 
The Congress does not decide 
More than two of the criteria below are fulfilled (but not all those in the 
‘good’ variable) 
Not fulfilled at all  None of the criteria below are fulfilled 
and/or  
State of the art 
Play the Game
55
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0056.png
Indicator 2.5 
The organisation defines a quorum in its governing document/s for its legislative and decision making 
bodies 
Explanation
A quorum (i.e., a minimum number of attendees required to conduct business and to cast
votes) prevents a small group of officials from monopolising power.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  No quorum in place 
Weak 
or 
A quorum set at 50% or less is in place in both bodies  
A quorum is in place in either the legislative  or the decision making body 
For the legislative body, it is at 50% OR for the decision making body, it is 
at 75% 
A quorum is in place in both the organisation’s legislative and decision 
making bodies 
For the legislative body, it is at 50% OR for the decision making body, it is 
at 75% 
A quorum is in place in the organisation’s legislative and decision making 
bodies 
For the legislative body, it is at 50%, and for the decision making body, it 
is at 75% 
a quorum is in place in either the legislative or the decision making body 
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
56
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0057.png
Indicator 2.6 
The organisation’s elected officials have a term limit 
Explanation
Term limits remedy high rates of re-election stemming directly from advantages incum-
bents enjoy over challengers (with seniority comes power). Moreover, they prevent that
office holders lose touch with their constituents – voter become apathetic when they as-
sume that the re-election of incumbents is inevitable. Term limits therefore make sure that
elections provide new ideas for solving problems and they prevent the concentration of
power (Cohen and Spitzer, 1992).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  No limitations are in place 
Weak 
Moderate 
An age limit is in place.  
Limitations are in place, but only for either the president or the governing 
body members and/or the limitation allows the president or the governing 
body members to stay in office for a (consecutive) period of more than 8 
years 
Limitations are in place for a number of consecutive terms only. 
Or 
Good 
The following limitations to terms of office are in place: 
President: 2 terms of 4 years 
Governing body members: 2 terms of 4 years 
State of the art 
The following limitations to terms of office are in place: 
 
In addition, only a fraction (e.g. one third) of the members of the board of 
directors is elected each time (preventing a hostile takeover and/or a sudden 
loss of expertise and experience) 
President: 2 terms of 4 years 
Governing body members: 2 terms of 4 years 
Judicial body members: 1 term of 6 years 
Chairmen of standing committees: 1 term of 8 years 
Play the Game
57
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0058.png
Indicator 2.7 
The organisation’s general assembly meets at least once a year 
Explanation
As a minimum, the target should be set at one general assembly meeting per year in order
to give member federations the possibility to scrutinise the financial accounts and general
policy of the past year.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all  The organisation’s general assembly meets less than once every 2 years 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
The organisation’s general assembly meets once every 2 years 
The organisation’s general assembly de facto meets at least once a year 
The organisation’s general assembly has to meet at least once a year 
The general assembly has to meet at least once a year and there are clear pro‐
cedures enshrined in the statutes for convening emergency and special meet‐
ings 
Indicator 2.8 
The organisation’s governing body meets regularly 
Explanation
The principal task of a governing body is to oversee the management of an organisation
(Carver and Carver 2001). Research suggests that governing body activity, measured by
meeting frequency, is an important dimension of board operations (Vafeas, 1999). Govern-
ing bodies that meet frequently are also more likely to perform their duties diligently and
in accordance with shareholders' interests (Lipton and Lorsch, 1992).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
The governing body meets once a year or less 
The governing body meets once every 6 months or less 
Good 
State of the art 
The governing body meets less than quarterly 
Governing body meetings are scheduled  
The governing body meets quarterly at the least 
Governing body meetings are scheduled 
The governing body meets more regularly than quarterly 
Governing body meetings are scheduled  
There are procedures for convening emergency or special meetings 
Play the Game
58
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0059.png
Indicator 2.9 
The organisation encourages gender equity with regard to its leading officials 
Explanation
Diversity in governing bodies is needed in order to ensure that everybody’s best interests
are being looked after (Katwala, 2000, p. 9). Importantly, studies have demonstrated that
female inclusion in boards enhances organisations’ performance (Brown, Brown and Ana-
stasopoulos, 2002; Fondas and Sassalos, 2000, Zelechowski and Bilimoria, 2004; Terjesen,
and Singh, 2009). Female directors also function as important role models, encouraging
other women to pursue similar careers (Sealy and Singh, 2010).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
The organisation has no gender equity policy 
The organisation has a gender equity policy, but not for the entire organisa‐
tion or it does not promotes gender equity in all leadership positions  
The organisation has  
or 
Good 
State of the art 
a quota for female governing body members 
The organisation adopts a 25% or higher quota for female governing 
body members 
The organisation has a gender equity policy for the entire organisation, 
which promotes gender equity in all leadership positions 
The organisation adopts a 25% or higher quota for female governing 
body members 
The organisation has a gender equity policy for the entire organisation, 
which promotes gender equity in all leadership positions 
The organisation has a policy in place which stresses gender equity 
throughout sport at all levels 
a gender equity policy for the entire organisation, which promotes gen‐
der equity in all leadership positions  
Play the Game
59
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0060.png
Indicator 2.10 
The organisation provides opportunity for athletes to be represented within the organisation 
Explanation
Including athletes in policy processes makes policies more effective because they come to
see ISFs’ decisions as their own decisions and provide specialised knowledge (Woods,
1999; Klijn and Koppenjan, 2004). Athlete inclusion also reduces the likelihood of legal
challenges, but only if they perceive their representatives participating in the policy process
as legitimate (Saward, 2005, Sørensen and Torfing, 2009). However, mere consultation of-
fers no assurance that athletes’ concerns and ideas will actually be taken into account; this
requires access to decision-making and decision-making power (Arnstein, 1969; Woods,
1999, Young, 2000).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
The organisation makes no formal efforts to involve athletes in its decision 
making processes 
Athletes are represented within the organisation, but the chair‐
man/woman of the athletes committee is not a member of the organi‐
sation’s governing body 
Athletes are represented but there is no athletes committee in place 
Athletes are represented within a specific athletes’ committee.  
The chairman/woman of the athletes committee is a member of the 
organisation’s governing body 
The chairman/woman of the athletes committee is not elected by the 
congress or by athletes  
he/she does not have voting authority 
Athletes are represented within a specific athletes’ committee.  
The chairman/woman of the athletes committee is a member of the 
organisation’s governing body 
The chairman/woman of the athletes committee is elected by congress 
Athletes are represented within a specific athletes’ committee.  
The chairman/woman of the athletes committee is a member of the 
organisation’s governing body 
The chairman/woman of the athletes committee is elected by athletes 
and/or 
Moderate 
Or 
Good 
State of the art 
 
Play the Game
60
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0061.png
3.3 Dimension 3. CHECKS AND BALANCES 
Indicator 3.1 
The organisation has an internal audit committee 
Explanation
The internal audit committee plays many important roles within an organisation, including
providing oversight to the internal audit. Internal audit is supplemental to external audit. It
can provide external auditors with business, activity and process knowledge, as well as
information on the risks facing the organisation. According to the Institute of Internal Au-
ditors, internal auditing evaluates and improves the effectiveness the nature of three specif-
ic processes:
“Risk management processes — identification and evaluation of potential risks that
might affect the achievement of objectives of an organisation and determination of ad-
equate corrective actions. A link can here be made to critical success factors.
Control processes — policies, procedures, and activities which ensure that risks are
kept within the limits defined by management in the risk management process.
Governance processes — procedures which allow stakeholders to evaluate risk and
control processes defined by management” (IIA 2013).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
The organisation has no internal audit committee 
Or 
A finance committee is present which only has the competence to re‐
view and recommend the draft budget, to prepare financial statements, 
and/or to study the external auditor’s report. 
The tasks and role of the committee are clearly defined in the organisa‐
tion’s statutes  
The committee oversees the internal audit 
The committee assesses the quality of the internal control system, in‐
cluding risk management 
The tasks and role of the committee are clearly defined in the organisa‐
tion’s statutes  
The chair of the committee is an external expert  
The committee members have the necessary expertise to perform their 
functions 
The committee oversees the internal audit  
An audit committee is present, but its tasks are not clearly defined in 
the statutes. 
Moderate 
Good 
Play the Game
61
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0062.png
State of the art 
The committee assesses the quality of the internal control system, in‐
cluding risk management  
The tasks and role of the committee are clearly defined in the organisa‐
tion’s statutes  
The chair of the committee is an external expert and a (non‐executive) 
member of the governing body  
The committee members have the necessary expertise to perform their 
functions 
The committee oversees the internal audit  
The committee draws up its own budget and is able to decide on the 
support of external advice at its own discretion 
The committee reviews the financial statements  
The committee assesses and monitor the quality of the internal control 
system, including risk management  
Indicator 3.2 
The organisation is externally audited according to internationally recognised standards 
Explanation
An independent external audit of ISFs’ finances provides stakeholders with the necessary
objective information on the organisation’s financial performance.
 
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
 Conditions 
No external audit 
The organisation’s finances are externally audited, but not according to in‐
ternationally recognised standards 
The organisation’s finances are externally audited according to international‐
ly recognised standards, but not on an annual basis  
The organisation’s finances are externally audited according to international‐
ly recognised standards 
The organisation is externally audited according to internationally rec‐
ognised standards  
The audit includes a review of  
the application and effectiveness of risk management procedures 
and risk assessment methodologies; 
a review of financial reports and accounting records, and; 
compliance with internal policies. 
Play the Game
62
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0063.png
Indicator 3.3 
The organisation adopts an integrated internal control and risk management system 
Explanation
Internal controls ensure that ISFs work in an effective manner with regard to operational
and financial performance goals (COSO, 2013).
14
An important part of an internal control
system is risk assessment. There are specific corruption-related risks in relation to ISFs.
Examples include funding being distributed to member federations, the hosting of events,
commercial contracts and financial controls over member associations (Pieth, 2011).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
 Conditions 
No internal control system 
Internal financial controls are not on a sufficiently high standard (COSO sys‐
tem or similar) 
Internal financial controls, applying the COSO system or similar, are on a 
sufficiently high standard 
State of the art 
Internal financial controls, applying the COSO system or similar, are on a 
sufficiently high standard  
In addition, the organisation adopts systematic controls to corruption 
risks connected with ISGBs 
Internal financial controls, applying the COSO system or similar, are on a 
sufficiently high standard 
In addition, the organisation adopts systematic controls to corruption 
risks associated with ISFs, including: 
payments to member federations 
payments to parties that are close to member federations 
Such payments are controlled either directly or indirectly (Pieth, 2011, p. 
21): 
Directly (each payment is controlled until it reaches the ultimate payee, 
for instance by entering into a direct contractual relationship with the 
latter; implementation and performance are then controlled through 
own accounting system, etc.) 
Indirectly (through access to audited financial statements; restricting 
cash payments to the absolute minimum; allow payments only to bank 
addresses or bank accounts which are defined in formal agreements; 
disallow any payments to bank addresses which are not in the country 
of residence or domicile of the payee; monitor the financial statements 
of the payees, which document the proper allocation of the funds) 
Important elements of an integrated control system (such as the presence of an accounting committee)
are included in other indicators. This indicator focuses on the presence of financial controls.
14
Play the Game
63
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0064.png
Indicator 3.4 
The organisation has or recognises an Ethics/Integrity Code for all its members and officials 
Explanation
An ethics code defines unacceptable behaviour within an organisation. International organ-
isations have issue checklists of components that should be part of such a code (e.g. Inter-
national Chamber of Commerce 2008). ISF’s codes of ethics need to include rules on gifts
and hospitality, political and charitable contributions, as well as the contracting of third
parties (Pieth, 2011).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
No ethics code within the organisation 
Ethics code available, applicable to staff and senior officials, is available but 
it does not include all the components in 4 
The ethics code, applicable to staff and senior officials,  includes the compo‐
nents in 4, but it is not clearly separated from the disciplinary code for ath‐
letes 
The ethics code includes the following components: 
The prohibition of bribery and extortion at all times and in any form 
Procedures covering the offer or receipt of gifts, hospitality or expenses 
in order to ensure that “such arrangements (a) are limited to reasonable 
and bona fide expenditures, and (b) do not improperly affect, or might 
be deemed to improperly affect, the outcome of a procurement or oth‐
er business transaction” (ICC, 2008, art. 5) 
Good 
State of the art 
In addition to the above components, the ethics code includes:  
Rules on charitable contributions 
Rules on the selection, contracting and supervision of third parties 
Training 
A helpline 
Furthermore, the organisation provides: 
Play the Game
64
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0065.png
Indicator 3.5 
The organisation has clear conflict of interest rules 
Explanation
Conflicts of interest require notification and disclosure and, in certain cases, mandatory
recusal from decisions. Conflicts of interest may arise in particular in certain high-risk areas
relating to ISFs. For instance, governing body members may directly benefit from the
choice of the organisation of events, commercial deals or the distribution of funds to mem-
ber federations (Pieth, 2011, p. 30).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
 Conditions 
No conflict of interest rules are in place 
Rules are in place but they are not sufficiently clear and/or they do not in‐
clude at least one of the conditions in 4 
General conflict of interest rules are in place but they do not include all con‐
ditions in 4 
Clear and consistent conflict of interest rules are in place.  
They include the duty to abstain from voting in cases of conflict of inter‐
ests regarding 
and  
State of the art 
define an appropriate threshold 
Furthermore, they include disclosure requirements and clearly describe 
the consequences for transgressors 
hosting decisions 
commercialisation decisions 
In addition to the points in 4, the organisation makes financial contributions 
to its member federations dependent upon the application of conflict of 
interest standards within these organisations 
Play the Game
65
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0066.png
Indicator 3.6 
The organisation has an independent body (e.g. Ethics Committee) to check the application of the 
rules referred in indicators 3.4 and 3.5 
Explanation
In order to ensure compliance with the code of ethics and conflict of interest rules, a com-
mittee should be in place that has the task of assessing compliance and of heading investi-
gations upon receiving reports of violations. Only then, ethical behaviour can fully enter
the daily decision-making and behaviour of ISF senior officials and staff (Weber, 1993, p.
430). Staff and governing body members need to explain and justify their conduct to the
committee, which should have the power to pose questions and pass judgement, after
which transgressors of the code face consequences (Bovens, 2007).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
There is no ethics committee or similar in place to check the application of the 
rules referred in indicators 3.4 and 3.5 
The committee (or the general disciplinary body) cannot initiate proceed‐
ings on its own initiative (i.e., without referral by the President, the Sec‐
retary General or the governing body) 
the committee members are not independent from the governing body 
and/or staff cannot report irregular behaviour committed by employees 
in the knowledge that they are afforded protection and safety (whistle‐
blower protection) 
The committee has the power to initiate proceedings on its own initiative
The committee members are not independent from the governing body 
and/or  
staff cannot report irregular behaviour in the knowledge that they are 
afforded (whistle‐blower) protection  
The committee members are independent from the governing body 
The committee has the power to initiate proceedings on its own initiative
Staff can report irregular behaviour in the knowledge that they are af‐
forded (whistle‐blower) protection 
The committee members are independent from the governing body 
The committee has the power to initiate proceedings on its own initiative
The committee has its own budget 
The committee members are objectively recruited 
The committee members are appointed by the congress 
Staff can report irregular behaviour in the knowledge that they are af‐
forded (whistle‐blower) protection 
Pre‐set sanctions (e.g. disciplinary reprimands) are determined in order 
to address minor breaches 
and/or  
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
66
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0067.png
The committee is separated into an investigatory and an adjudicatory 
chamber or a similar separation of powers is provided 
Indicator 3.7 
The organisation’s decisions can be contested through internal channels specified in its governing  
document/s 
Explanation
The right of any national association, club, player, official or member to appeal any deci-
sion by which they are directly affected constitutes an important check.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
The organisation’s decisions cannot be contested 
Moderate 
or 
Good 
The conditions in 4 are fulfilled, but the secretary general or president 
has the discretionary authority to refer cases to the committee. 
Any national association, club, player, official or member directly affect‐
ed by a decision shall be entitled to appeal 
The members of the appeal committee may not belong to the governing 
body or to any of the standing committees of the organisation 
The members of the appeal committee may not sit on the committee if 
the case being dealt with concerns themselves or players, clubs, officials 
or any other members of the national association to which they belong 
Any national association, club, player, official or member directly affect‐
ed by a decision shall be entitled to appeal 
The members of the appeal committee may not belong to the governing 
body or to any of the standing committees of the organisation 
The members of the appeal committee may not sit on the committee if 
the case being dealt with concerns themselves or players, clubs, officials 
or any other members of the national association to which they belong 
The parties concerned are entitled to a hearing if they so desire 
The members of the appeal committee belong to the governing body or 
to any of the standing committees of the organisation 
And/or not every national association, club, player, official or member 
directly affected by a decision shall be entitled to appeal 
Executive body decisions cannot be appealed internally 
Any national association, club, player, official or member directly affect‐
ed by a decision shall be entitled to appeal 
The members of the appeal committee may not belong to the governing 
body or to any of the standing committees of the organisation 
State of the art 
Play the Game
67
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0068.png
3.4 Dimension 4. SOLIDARITY 
Indicator 4.1 
The organisation allocates specific resources for the global development of grass‐roots activities 
Explanation
As the custodians of sport, a public good, ISFs have a responsibility for fostering the global
development of grass-roots activities. According to Eurostrategies
et al.
(2011),
“grassroots
sport covers all sport disciplines practiced by non-professionals and organised on a nation-
al level through national sport” (Eurostrategies
et al.,
2011, p. 13).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
 Conditions 
The organisation does not allocate specific resources for the global devel‐
opment of grass‐roots activities and does not promote the global develop‐
ment of grass‐roots activities 
The organisation promotes the global development of grass‐roots activities, 
but does not allocate specific resources 
The organisation allocates specific resources for the global development of 
grass‐roots activities, but it does not consolidate these under a comprehen‐
sive strategy (approved or not approved by the Congress) 
The organisation allocates specific resources for the global development 
of grass‐roots activities and it consolidates these under a comprehen‐
sive strategy (not approved by the Congress) 
The organisation allocates specific resources for the global development 
of grass‐roots activities  
The different programmes are consolidated under a comprehensive 
strategy, approved by the Congress 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
68
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0069.png
Indicator 4.2 
The organisation has a well‐defined Social Responsibility (SR) strategy and/or programme 
Explanation
In the broad sense, (Corporate) Social Responsibility (SR) can be defined as “a continuing
commitment by an organisation to behave ethically and contribute to economic develop-
ment, while also improving the quality of life of its employees, the local community, and
society at large” (Watts and Holme, 1999).
15
SR does not cover a single, comprehensive
activity (Lindgreen, Swaen and Johnston, 2009). By taking a strategic approach to social
responsibility, organisations can determine what activities they devote to SR. By planning
out SR as part of an organisation’s overall plan, it is ensured that (commercial) activities do
not overshadow the need to behave socially responsible. This indicator looks at SR in a
more narrow sense and focuses on contributing to society, while leaving out the elements
that have been treated in other indicators.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
The organisation does not make efforts towards achieving the area’s in score 
4 and 5 
The organisation makes certain efforts towards achieving the area’s in score 
4 and 5, but it does not have a well‐defined SR strategy and/or pro‐
gramme(s) 
The organisation makes certain efforts towards achieving the area’s in 
score 4 and 5, but it does not have a well‐defined SR strategy and/or 
programme(s)
 
The organisation makes serious efforts (investments, programmes 
and/or international cooperation) to mitigate the negative externalities 
of international organised sports (e.g. human trafficking, doping preven‐
tion, match fixing, money laundering, etc.) 
Moderate 
Good 
The organisation has a well‐defined SR strategy and/or programme(s) 
 
The strategy or programme(s) cover one of the following areas: 
Mitigating environmental degradation (not including degradation 
through event(s) )  
Improving the social, cultural, educational or psychological circumstanc‐
es of marginalised and/or fractured communities (not including anti‐
discrimination and sexual harassment; legacy requirements for events; 
development of grassroots sports) 
 
In addition, the organisation makes serious efforts (investments, pro‐
grammes and/or international cooperation) to mitigate the negative exter‐
nalities of international organised sports (e.g. human trafficking, doping pre‐
15
By referring to “Social Responsibility”, ISO 26000 extends the idea of “Corporate Social Responsibility”
(CSR) from private businesses to other organisations, such as NGOs or ISFs.
Play the Game
69
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0070.png
vention, match fixing, money laundering, etc.) 
State of the art 
The organisation has a well‐defined SR strategy and/or programme(s) 
 
The strategy or programme(s) cover all of the following areas: 
Mitigating environmental degradation (not including degradation 
through event(s) ) 
Improving the social, cultural, educational or psychological circumstanc‐
es of marginalised and/or fractured communities (not including anti‐
discrimination and sexual harassment; legacy requirements for events; 
development of grassroots sports) 
 
In addition, the organisation makes serious efforts (investments, pro‐
grammes and/or international cooperation) to mitigate the negative exter‐
nalities of international organised sports (e.g. human trafficking, doping pre‐
vention, match fixing, money laundering, etc.) 
Indicator 4.3 
The organisation has legacy requirements for communities in which its events are hosted 
Explanation
Large sport events can have both positive and negative effects on communities in which
they are hosted. ISFs have a responsibility to ensure that their events live up to their full
potential, ensuring positive and minimising long-term negative effects.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
There are no legacy requirements. 
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
The organisation adopts legacy requirements for the hosting of its major 
event 
These requirements are not specific and clear 
The organisation adopts social or sporting legacy requirements 
These requirements are specific and clear 
Bids to host the major event are evaluated based amongst others on the 
fulfilment of these requirements 
The organisation adopts social and sporting legacy requirements for the 
hosting of its major event 
These requirements are specific and clear 
Bids to host the major event are evaluated based amongst others on the 
fulfilment of these requirements by means of a scoring system 
The organisation adopts social and sporting legacy requirements for the 
hosting all its events 
These requirements are specific and clear 
Bids to host all events are evaluated based amongst others on the ful‐
filment of these requirements by means of a scoring system 
The fulfilment of these requirements is evaluated ex post 
Play the Game
70
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0071.png
Indicator 4.4 
The organisation adopts an environmental management system (ISO 14001, EMAS or similar) for its 
major events 
Explanation
Environmental management systems are (usually voluntary) tools for public administra-
tions as well as private companies. They are intended to help organisations to optimise
their production processes, reducing environmental impacts and making more effective
use of resources (European Commission, 2008, p. 9). Consequently, they are suited as a tool
for reducing the environmental impacts of sport events.
16
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
 Conditions 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
The organisation does not adopt environmental requirements for its major 
events 
Legacy requirements for the hosting of the organisation’s major event 
are adopted 
These requirements are not specific and clear 
Legacy requirements for the hosting of the organisation’s major event 
are adopted 
These requirements are specific and clear 
Bids to host the major event are evaluated based amongst others on 
the fulfilment of these requirements 
An environmental management system (ISO, EMAS or similar) is 
adopted for  the organisation’s major events 
Bids to host the major event are evaluated based amongst others on 
the fulfilment this requirement 
The organisation obliges  an environmental management system (ISO, 
EMAS or similar) for its major events 
1
2
3
Moderate 
4
Good 
5
State of the art 
For instance, several sport events and many sport facilities have already received EU eco-management
and audit scheme (EMAS) certification. TOROC, the Organising Committee for the 2006 Winter Olympic
Games in Turin, has produced a handbook on how to apply EMAS to sporting events which includes
concrete steps towards registration and examples of activities (see TOROC, 2006).
16
Play the Game
71
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0072.png
Indicator 4.5 
The organisation offers consulting to member federations in the areas of organisations and manage‐
ment through workshops, one to one advice or similar 
Explanation
ISFs can assist national sports federations to become more professional in their approach,
and more able to maximise their organisational advantages. For instance, ISFs can dissemi-
nate best practice on a range of issues related to good governance (Holt, 2006, p. 158).
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
Good 
 Conditions 
The organisation does not offer any form of consulting to member federa‐
tions in the areas of organisations and management  
The organisation provides basic information on its website in the areas of 
organisations and management, directed towards its member federations 
The organisation disseminates documentation in the areas of organisations 
and management among its member federations 
The organisation offers consulting to member federations in the areas of 
organisations and management through workshops, one to one advice or 
similar 
The organisation adopts a comprehensive strategy for consulting to member 
federations in the areas of organisations and management through work‐
shops, one to one advice or similar 
State of the art 
Play the Game
72
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0073.png
Indicator 4.6 
Representatives from economically weaker member federations can apply for support to attend the 
general assembly 
Explanation
The congress has an important monitoring function with regard to the governing body
(Strøm, 2000). Yet it can be rather costly for national sporting delegates to attend congress
meetings. In order to achieve a high attendance rate, ISFs can reimburse travel expenses
and hotel stays for economically disadvantaged members federations. In addition, new
communication technology can be used as an enabler.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
Moderate 
 Conditions 
The organisation does not provide support for economically weaker 
member federations 
The organisation provides support for federations, but it is not specifi‐
cally directed towards economically weaker federations 
Representatives from economically disadvantaged member federations 
can apply for support to attend the general assembly or new communi‐
cation technology (e.g. proxy voting) is used as an enabler 
There are however no clearly defined application procedures available 
Representatives from economically disadvantaged member federations 
can apply for support to attend the general assembly or new communi‐
cation technology is used as an enabler 
There are clearly defined application procedures available 
Representatives from economically disadvantaged member federations 
can apply for support to attend the general assembly  
Reimbursed expenses are internally audited and reported 
New communication technology is used as an enabler 
There are clearly defined application procedures available 
Good 
State of the art 
Play the Game
73
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0074.png
Indicator 4.7 
The organisation adopts a clear anti‐discrimination policy 
Explanation
Discrimination and harassment can be based on race, ethnic origin or skin colour, nationali-
ty, gender, sexual orientation, ability, religious or political convictions, illness, sensory im-
pairments, learning difficulties, age, and so on. ISFs have a responsibility to combat dis-
crimination and harassment in all levels of sport.
17
In addition, internal anti-discrimination
and anti-harassment policies contribute to providing a work environment free of discrimi-
nation and/or harassment.
Operationalisation 
Score 
 
Not fulfilled at all 
Weak 
 Conditions 
The organisation does not adopt any of the discussed policies. 
The organisation takes certain measures towards fighting one of the follow‐
ing: 
Internal anti‐discrimination and anti‐harassment measures;  
Moderate 
Good 
State of the art 
Measures directed towards combating discrimination in sport. 
The organisation only adopts one of the following: 
A clear internal anti‐discrimination and anti‐harassment policy;  
A clear policy directed towards combating discrimination in sport. 
The organisation adopts a clear internal anti‐discrimination and anti‐
harassment policy;  
The organisation adopts a clear policy directed towards combating dis‐
crimination in sport. 
The organisation adopts a clear internal anti‐discrimination and anti‐
harassment policy; 
The organisation adopts a clear policy directed towards combating dis‐
crimination in sport; 
The policies address discrimination based on at least 3 of the following: 
Race, ethnic origin or skin colour 
Nationality  
Gender 
Ability 
Sexual orientation 
Religious or political convictions 
Illness 
Sensory impairments 
Learning difficulties 
Age. 
According to the Olympic Charter, “[t]he practice of sport is a human right. Every individual must have
the possibility of practicing sport, without discrimination of any kind and in the Olympic spirit” (IOC,
2013a).
17
Play the Game
74
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0075.png
4. Results of the Sports Governance Observer survey 
This section presents the results of the application of the Sports Governance Observer on
the 35 Olympic ISFs. After a brief presentation of the overall results, the SGO indexes and
the dimension scores of the individual federations are presented. Furthermore, the meth-
odological sheets of the Sport Governance Observer and the federations’ scores on individ-
ual indicators allow for a concise overview of the main strengths and weaknesses of each
federation.
4.1 Overall results 
It must be stressed that the SGO index reflects the presence of basic criteria of good gov-
ernance. Medium-size federations should be expected to have an SGO index close to 75%,
while large federations should achieve a score higher than 75%.
The SGO index of the 35
federations combined is 45.4%, with 26 federations (74%) scoring less than 50%. This over-
all score points at severe governance problems in ISFs.
While having a high SGO index
does not rule out the occurrence of corruption, it can be expected that the absence of basic
criteria of good governance increases the likelihood of opportunistic and unethical behav-
iour.
Table 3: SGO Index and SGO scores – all 35 federations 
All 35 federations 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.99 
2.81 
2.68 
2.79 
 
SGO Index 
49.6% 
45.2% 
42.0% 
44.9% 
45.4% 
 
Play the Game
75
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0076.png
Figure 4: 35 Olympic international sports federations 
Transparency
2.99
Solidarity
2.78
2.81
Democratic
process
2.67
Checks and
balances
 
The scoring scale 
 
1. Not fulfilled at all 
 
2. Weak 
 
3. Moderate 
 
4. Good 
 
5. State of the art 
As table 3 and figure 4 show, the federations generally achieve modest to weak scores on
all dimensions, but especially worrisome is the general lack of decent checks and balances
in the federations. For instance, only five federations (14%) have a robust ethics committee;
only six federations (17%) have adequate conflict of interest rules in place; and none of the
federations has adequate term limits in place.
Furthermore, only four federations (11%) perform integrity and professional checks on
candidates standing for elections; only six federations (17%) publish decent general activity
reports online; none of the federations selects event hosts on the basis of a transparent and
objective process; only five federations (14%) have a robust ethics committee; and none of
the federations has adequate term limits in place.
Regarding solidarity, problems are particularly situated in a lack of sustainability require-
ments for major events.
 
Play the Game
76
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0077.png
AIBA – International Boxing Association 
The SGO index for AIBA is 46.6%.
Main strengths are:
Good election procedures for senior officials
Adequate conflict of interest rules and ethics code
Main weaknesses are:
moderate to weak public transparency
No frequent general assembly and decision-making body meetings
Lack of internal audit and ethics committee.
Table 4: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – AIBA 
AIBA 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.80 
3.13 
2.67 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
45.0% 
53.1% 
41.7% 
 N/A 
46.6% 
 
Figure 5: AIBA – International Boxing Association 
Transparency
2.80
Solidarity
3.13
Democratic
process
2.67
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
77
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0078.png
BWF – Badminton World Federation 
The SGO index for BWF is 56.2%.
Main strengths are:
Good reporting transparency
Adequate athlete representation
Good social responsibility programme
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Ethics and audit committees.
Table 5: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – BWF 
BWF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.25 
3.00 
3.17 
3.57 
 
SGO Index 
56.3% 
50.0% 
54.2% 
64.3% 
56.2% 
 
Figure 6: BWF – Badminton World Federation 
Transparency
3.25
Solidarity 3.57
3.00
Democratic
process
3.17
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
78
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0079.png
FEI – Fédération Equestre Internationale 
The SGO index for FEI is 75.6%.
Main strengths are:
Excellent checks and balances
Very transparent organization
Robust election procedures.
Main weakness is
The procedure for allocation of events
Table 6: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FEI 
FEI  
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
4.08 
3.80 
4.50 
3.71 
 
SGO Index 
77.1% 
70.0% 
87.5% 
67.9% 
75.6% 
 
Figure 7: FEI – Fédération Equestre Internationale 
Transparency
4.08
Solidarity 3.71
3.80 Democratic
process
4.50
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
79
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0080.png
FIBA – International Basketball Federation 
The SGO index for FIBA is 39.6%.
Main strengths are:
Solid ethics code
Social responsibility and development programmes
Excellent consulting services to member federations
Main weaknesses are:
Inadequate election procedures
No frequent general assembly meetings
No robust ethics committee.
Table 7: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIBA 
FIBA  
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.70 
2.56 
3.00 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
42.5% 
38.9% 
50.0% 
N/A 
43.8% 
 
Figure 8: FIBA – International Basketball Federation 
Transparency
2.70
Solidarity
2.56
Democratic
process
2.50
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
80
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0081.png
FIBT – International Bobsleigh and Skeleton Federation 
The SGO index for FIBT is 40.9%.
Main strengths are:
Solid ethics code
Good athletes representation
Main weaknesses are:
Weak reporting transparency
Lack of term limits
Weak ethics committee
Table 8: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIBT 
FIBT  
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.55 
2.70 
2.67 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
38.6% 
42.5% 
41.7% 
 N/A 
40.9% 
 
Figure 9: International Bobsleight and Skeleton Federation 
Transparency
2.55
Solidarity
2.70
Democratic
process
2.67
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
81
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0082.png
FIE ‐ International Fencing Federation 
The SGO index for FIE is 51.1%.
Main strengths are
Good reporting transparency
Athletes representation
Election procedures
Main weaknesses are
Lack of internal checks
Table 9: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIE 
FIE  
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.90 
3.40 
1.83 
N/A 
 
SGO Index 
72.5% 
60.0% 
20.8% 
N/A 
51.1% 
 
Figure 10: FIE – International Fencing Federation 
Transparency
3.90
Solidarity
3.40
Democratic
process
1.83
Checks and
balances
Play the Game
82
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0083.png
FIFA – Fédération Internationale de Football Association 
The SGO index for FIFA is 67.8%.
Main strengths are:
Robust internal audit committee
Good ethics committee
Solidarity and development programmes
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Lack of gender equity policy
Inadequate procedure for allocation of world cups
Weak legacy and sustainability requirements for world cups
Table 10: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIFA 
FIFA  
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.92 
3.10 
3.83 
4.00 
 
SGO Index 
72.9% 
52.5% 
70.8% 
75.0% 
67.8% 
 
Figure 11: Fédération Internationale de Football Association 
Transparency
3.92
Solidarity 4.00
3.10
Democratic
process
3.83
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
83
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0084.png
FIG – International Gymnastics Federation 
The SGO index for FIG is 45.3%.
Main strengths are:
Athlete representation
Development programme
Consultancy programme for member federations
Main weaknesses are:
The allocation procedure for main event
Weak ethics code and conflict of interest rules
Lack of decent audit and ethics committees
Table 11: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIG 
FIG 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.91 
3.10 
2.67 
2.57 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
SGO Index 
47.7% 
52.5% 
41.7% 
39.3% 
45.3% 
 
Figure 12: FIG ‐ International Gymnastics Federation 
Transparency
2.91
Solidarity
2.57
3.10
Democratic
process
2.67
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
84
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0085.png
FIH – International Hockey Federation 
The SGO index for FIH is 43.2%.
Main strengths are:
Athlete representation
Adequate ethics code
Development and social responsibility programmes
Main weaknesses are:
No event reports
No internal audit and ethics committees
Table 12: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIH 
FIH 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.60 
2.75 
2.83 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
40.0% 
43.8% 
45.8% 
N/A  
43.2% 
 
Figure 13: FIH – International Hockey Federation 
Transparency
2.60
Solidarity
2.75
Democratic
process
2.83
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
85
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0086.png
FIL – International Luge Federation 
The SGO index for FIL is 34.2%.
Main strengths are:
Annual general assembly meetings
Elections of senior officials
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Lack of gender equity policy
Absence of decent internal checks
Table 13: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIL 
FIL  
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.55 
2.56 
2.00 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
38.6% 
38.9% 
25.0% 
 N/A 
34.2% 
 
Figure 14: FIL – International Luge Federation 
Transparency
2.55
Solidarity
2.56
Democratic
process
2.00
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
86
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0087.png
FINA – Fédération Internationale de Natation  
The SGO index for FINA is 43.8%.
Main strengths are:
Elections of senior officials
Quorums for legislative and decision-making bodies
Robust ethics code
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of decent internal audit and ethics committees
Weak allocation procedure for main event
Table 14: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FINA 
FINA 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.80 
2.63 
2.83 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
45.0% 
40.6% 
45.8% 
 N/A 
43.8% 
 
Figure 15: FINA – Fédération Internationale de Natation 
Transparency
2.80
Solidarity
2.63
Democratic
process
2.83
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
87
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0088.png
FIS – International Ski Federation 
The SGO index for FIS is 61.4%.
Main strengths are:
Very good reporting transparency
Solid election procedures and ethics code
Excellent solidarity
Main weaknesses are:
Weak ethics and internal audit committee
Lack of term limits
No regular general assembly and decision-making body meetings
Table 15: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIS 
FIS 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
4.08 
2.40 
3.33 
4.00 
 
SGO Index 
77.1% 
35.0% 
58.3% 
75.0% 
61.4% 
 
Figure 16: FIS ‐ International Ski Federation 
Transparency
4.08
Solidarity
4.00
2.40
Democratic
process
3.33
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
88
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0089.png
FISA – International Rowing Federation 
The SGO index for FISA is 54.5%.
Main strengths are:
Overall transparency
Solid ethics code
Good athlete representation
Good social responsibility and development programmes
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of quorums for legislative and decision-making bodies
Weak ethics and audit committees
Table 16: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FISA 
FISA 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.92 
2.80 
3.43 
2.57 
 
SGO Index 
72.9% 
45.0% 
60.7% 
39.3% 
54.5% 
 
Figure 17: FISA – International Rowing Federation 
Transparency
3.92
Solidarity
2.57
2.80
Democratic
process
3.43
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
89
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0090.png
FIVB – Fédération Internationale de Volleyball 
The SGO index for FIVB is 38.1%.
Main strengths are:
Solid ethics code
Development programme
Main weaknesses are:
Not all senior officials are elected
Weak ethics and audit committees
No regular legislative and decision-making body meetings
Table 17: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – FIVB 
FIVB 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.63 
2.44 
2.50 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
40.6% 
36.1% 
37.5% 
 N/A 
38.1% 
 
 
Figure 18: FIVB – Fédération Internationale de Volleyball
Transparency
2.63
Solidarity
2.44
Democratic
process
2.50
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
90
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0091.png
IAAF – International Association of Athletics Federations  
The SGO index for IAAF is 52.5%.
Main strengths are:
Good athlete representation
Election of senior officials
Robust ethics commission
Solid development and social responsibility programmes
Main weaknesses are:
Weak audit committee
Lack of quorums for legislative and decision-making bodies
Table 18: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IAAF 
IAAF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.00 
2.70 
3.60 
N/A  
 
SGO Index 
50.0% 
42.5% 
65.0% 
 N/A 
52.5% 
 
Figure 19: IAAF – International Association of Athletics Federation 
Transparency
3.00
Solidarity
2.70
Democratic
process
3.60
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
91
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0092.png
IBU – International Biathlon Union 
The SGO index for IBU is 38.5%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures
Solid development programme
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of event reports
Lack of term limits
Weak internal audit and ethics committees
Weak ethics code and conflict of interests rules
Table 19: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IBU 
IBU 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.92 
2.50 
2.17 
2.57 
 
 
SGO Index 
47.9% 
37.5% 
29.2% 
39.3% 
38.5% 
Figure 20: IBU – International Biathlon Union 
Transparency
2.92
Solidarity
2.57
2.50
Democratic
process
2.17
Checks and
balances
 
 
 
Play the Game
92
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0093.png
ICF – International Canoe Federation 
The SGO index for ICF is 42.5%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures
Quorums in legislative and decision-making bodies
Very good athlete representation
Main weaknesses are:
Weak procedures for deciding host of main event
Lack of audit and ethics committees
Lack of term limits
No annual general assembly meetings
Table 20: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ICF 
ICF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.90 
3.00 
2.20 
 N/A 
 
 
SGO Index 
47.5% 
50.0% 
30.0% 
 N/A 
42.5% 
Figure 21: ICF – International Canoe Federation 
Transparency
2.90
Solidarity
3.00
Democratic
process
2.20
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
93
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0094.png
IGF – International Golf Federation  
The SGO index for IGF is 27.8%.
Main strengths are:
Presence of quorums in legislative and decision-making bodies
Transparency of governing body documents
Main weaknesses are:
Overall lack of democratic processes and internal checks
Table 21: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IGF 
IGF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.33 
2.00 
2.00 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
33.3% 
25.0% 
25.0% 
 N/A 
27.8% 
 
Figure 22: IGF – International Golf Federation  
Transparency
2.33
Solidarity
2.00
Democratic
process
2.00
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
94
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0095.png
IHF – International Handball Federation  
The SGO index for IHF is 48.3%.
Main strengths are:
Elections of senior officials
Good athletes representation
Solid ethics code, ethics committee, and conflict of interest rules
Main weaknesses are:
Weak internal audit committee
Weak allocation process for major event
Lack of term limits
Table 22: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IHF 
IHF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.50 
2.70 
3.60 
 N/A 
 
SGO Index 
37.5% 
42.5% 
65.0% 
 N/A 
48.3% 
 
Figure 23: IHF – International Handball Federation  
Transparency
2.50
Solidarity
2.70
Democratic
process
3.60
Checks and
balances
 
 
 
Play the Game
95
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0096.png
IIHF – International Ice Hockey Federation 
The SGO index for IIHF is 52.8%.
Main strengths are:
Elections of all decision-making body members
Solid internal audit committee
Ethics code
Development programme
Main weaknesses are:
Weak athlete representation
No nominations committee
No ethics committee.
Table 23: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IIHF 
IIHF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.33 
3.00 
3.00 
N/A  
 
 
SGO Index 
58.3% 
50.0% 
50.0% 
N/A 
52.8% 
Figure 24: IIHF – International Ice Hockey Federation 
Transparency
3.33
Solidarity
3.00
Democratic
process
3.00
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
96
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0097.png
IJF – International Judo Federation  
The SGO index for IJF is 36.2%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures for senior officials and athlete representation
Food social responsibility programme
Main weaknesses are:
Weak main event allocation procedure
Lack of decent ethics code and conflict of interest rules
Lack of ethics and audit committees
Table 24: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IJF 
IJF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.67 
2.50 
2.33 
2.29 
 
SGO Index 
41.7% 
37.5% 
33.3% 
32.1% 
36.2% 
 
Figure 25: IJF – International Judo Federation 
Transparency
2.67
Solidarity
2.29
2.50
Democratic
process
2.33
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
97
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0098.png
ISAF – International Sailing Federation  
The SGO index for ISAF is 55.2%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures for senior officials
Good athlete representation
Robust ethics committee
Good social responsibility programme
Main weaknesses are:
Weak reporting transparency
No quorum for decision-making and legislative bodies
No decent conflict of interest rules
Table 25: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ISAF 
ISAF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.88 
3.50 
3.25 
 N/A 
 
 
SGO Index 
46.9% 
62.5% 
56.3% 
 N/A 
55.2% 
Figure 26: ISAF – International Sailing Federation 
Transparency
2.88
Solidarity
3.50
Democratic
process
3.25
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
98
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0099.png
ISSF – International Shooting Sport Federation  
The SGO index for ISSF is 27.3%.
Main strengths are:
Good athlete representation
Election of senior officials
Main weaknesses are:
Overall weak solidarity and checks and balances
Table 26: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ISSF 
ISSF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.73 
2.40 
1.67 
1.57 
 
SGO Index 
43.2% 
35.0% 
16.7% 
14.3% 
27.3% 
 
 
Figure 27: ISSF – International Shooting Sport Federation 
Transparency
2.73
Solidarity
1.57
2.40
Democratic
process
1.67
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
99
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0100.png
ISU – International Skating Union 
The SGO index for ISU is 41.5%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures and ethics code
Environmental requirements for major events
Solid development programme
Main weaknesses are:
No annual general assembly meetings
Weak main event allocation procedure
Lack of decent ethics and internal audit committees
Table 27: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ISU 
ISU 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.58 
2.70 
2.50 
2.86 
 
SGO Index 
39.6% 
42.5% 
37.5% 
46.4% 
41.5% 
 
 
Figure 28: ISU ‐ International Skating Union 
Transparency
2.58
Solidarity
2.86
2.70
Democratic
process
2.50
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
100
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0101.png
ITF – International Tennis Federation  
The SGO index for ITF is 37.0%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures and ethics code
Development programme and solidarity programme
Main weaknesses are:
No gender equity policy
Weak athlete representation
Lack of decent ethics and internal audit committees
Table 28: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ITF 
ITF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.20 
2.89 
2.67 
2.17 
 
SGO Index 
30.0% 
47.2% 
41.7% 
29.2% 
37.0% 
 
Figure 29: ITF – International Tennis Federation  
Transparency
2.20
Solidarity
2.17
2.89
Democratic
process
2.67
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
101
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0102.png
ITTF – International Table Tennis Federation  
The SGO index for ITTF is 45.8%.
Main strengths are:
Good reporting transparency
Solid election procedures, solidarity and event programmes
Consultancy to member federations
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of legacy requirements for main events
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
Table 29: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ITTF 
ITTF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.50 
3.00 
1.83 
3.00 
 
SGO Index 
62.5% 
50.0% 
20.8% 
50.0% 
45.8% 
 
Figure 30: ITTF – International Table Tennis Federation 
Transparency
3.50
Solidarity
3.00
3.00
Democratic
process
1.83
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
102
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0103.png
ITU – International Triathlon Union 
The SGO index for ITU is 30.4%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures
Main weaknesses are:
Very weak procedures for the allocation of the major event
Lack of term limits
Irregular decision-making body meetings
Lack of event reports
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
Table 30: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – ITU 
ITU 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.33 
3.00 
1.67 
1.86 
 
SGO Index 
33.3% 
50.0% 
16.7% 
21.4% 
30.4% 
 
Figure 31: ITU – The International Triathlon Union 
Transparency
2.33
Solidarity
1.86
3.00
Democratic
process
1.67
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
103
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0104.png
IWF – International Weightlifting Federation 
The SGO index for IWF is 30.4%.
Main strengths are:
Strong development programme
Strong ethics code and conflict of interest rules
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Weak procedures for the allocation of the major event
Lack of term limits
Irregular decision-making body meetings
Lack of event reports
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
Table 31: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – IWF 
IWF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.82 
2.60 
2.83 
2.00 
 
SGO Index 
45.5% 
40.0% 
45.8% 
25.0% 
39.1% 
 
Figure 32: IWF – International Weightlifting Federation 
Transparency
2.81
Solidarity
2.00
2.60
Democratic
process
2.83
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
104
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0105.png
UCI – Union Cycliste Internationale 
The SGO index for UCI is 47.6%.
Main strengths are:
Solid ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics commission
Strong development programme
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of good audit committee
Lack of decent term limits
No quorum for legislative and decision-making bodies
Table 32: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – UCI 
UCI 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.27 
2.44 
3.00 
N/A  
 
SGO Index 
56.8% 
36.1% 
50.0% 
N/A 
47.6% 
 
Figure 33: UCI – Union Cycliste Internationale 
Transparency
3.27
Solidarity
2.44
Democratic
process
3.00
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
105
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0106.png
UIPM – Union Internationale de Pentathlon Moderne 
The SGO index for UIPM is 46.2%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures and athletes representation
Overall strong solidarity
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Weak procedures for the allocation of the major event
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
Table 33: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – UIPM 
UIPM 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.75 
3.10 
1.83 
3.71 
 
SGO Index 
43.8% 
52.5% 
20.8% 
67.9% 
46.2% 
 
Figure 34: UIPM – Union Internationale de Pentathlon Moderne 
Transparency
2.75
Solidarity
3.71
1.83
3.10
Democratic
process
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
106
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0107.png
UWW – United World Wrestling 
The SGO index for UWW is 42.1%.
Main strengths are:
Strong development and anti-discrimination programmes
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Lack of decent event reports
Weak procedures for the allocation of the major event
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
Table 34: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – UWW 
UWW 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.00 
2.22 
2.83 
N/A  
 
SGO Index 
50.0% 
30.6% 
45.8% 
N/A 
42.1% 
 
Figure 35: UWW – United World Wrestling 
Transparency
3.00
Solidarity
2.22
Democratic
process
2.83
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
107
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0108.png
WA – World Archery Federation 
The SGO index for WA is 45.3%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures and athlete representation
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Lack of decent event reports
Weak procedures for the allocation of the major event
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
No regular legislative and decision-making body meetings
Table 35: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – WA 
WA 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.00 
2.60 
2.83 
N/A  
 
SGO Index 
50.0% 
40.0% 
45.8% 
N/A  
45.3% 
 
Figure 36: WA – World Archery Federation 
Transparency
3.00
Solidarity
2.60
Democratic
process
2.83
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
108
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0109.png
WCF – World Curling Federation 
The SGO index for WCF is 39.3%.
Main strengths are:
Solid election procedures
Main weaknesses are:
Overall very weak internal checks and solidarity
Table 36: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – WCF 
WCF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.08 
3.20 
2.00 
2.00 
 
SGO Index 
52.1% 
55.0% 
25.0% 
25.0% 
39.3% 
 
Figure 37: WCF – World Curling Federation 
Transparency
3.08
Solidarity
2.00
3.20
Democratic
process
2.00
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
109
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0110.png
WR ‐ World Rugby 
The SGO index for WR is 45.8%.
Main strengths are:
Good reporting transparency
Overall good solidarity
Solid election procedures
Main weaknesses are:
Weak main event allocation procedure
Lack of decent ethics and internal audit committee
Lack of ethics code and decent conflict of interest rules
Table 37: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – WR 
WR 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
3.00 
2.90 
2.00 
3.43 
 
 
SGO Index 
50.0% 
47.5% 
25.0% 
60.7% 
45.8% 
Figure 38: WR ‐ World Rugby 
Transparency
3.00
Solidarity 3.43
2.90
Democratic
process
2.00
Checks and
balances
 
 
Play the Game
110
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0111.png
WTF – World Taekwondo Federation 
The SGO index for WTF is 44.2%.
Main strengths are:
Very strong election procedures
Solid ethics code
Consulting to member federations
Main weaknesses are:
Lack of term limits
Lack of decent event reports
Weak procedures for the allocation of the major event
Lack of decent ethics code, conflict of interest rules, and ethics and internal audit
committee
No regular decision-making body meetings
Table 38: Overall SGO Index and SGO scores – WTF 
WTF 
Dimension 
Transparency 
Democratic process 
Checks and balances 
Solidarity 
Overall 
 
  
SGO score  
(on a scale from 1‐5) 
2.92 
2.90 
2.83 
2.43 
 
SGO Index 
47.9% 
47.5% 
45.8% 
35.7% 
44.2% 
 
Figure 39: WTF – World Taekwondo Federation 
Transparency
2.92
Solidarity
2.43
2.90
Democratic
process
2.83
Checks and
balances
 
Play the Game
111
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0112.png
Table 39: Scores of the 35 Olympic ISFs on the individual indicators of the Sports Governance 
Observer  
 
Transparency 
1.1 
1.2 
1.3 
1.4 
1.5 
1.6 
1.7 
1.8 
1.9 
1.10 
1.11 
1.12 
Mean 
Percentage 
Democratic process 
2.1 
2.2 
2.3 
2.4 
2.5 
2.6 
2.7 
2.8 
2.9 
2.10 
Mean 
Percentage 
Checks and balances 
3.1 
3.2 
3.3 
3.4 
3.5 
3.6 
3.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Solidarity 
4.1 
4.2 
4.3 
4.4 
4.5 
4.6 
4.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Total 
SGO index 
 
 
 
 
 
 
  
3.57 
4
4
3
3
5
3
4
3.71
2.75
264
4
4
4
5
2
2
5
5
5
4.00
4
1
1
1
4
5
2
2.57
5
4
4
 
 
5
5
2
2
4
3
5
4
3
5
3
2
2
2
3
2
3
3
3
4
4
1
3
3
1
5
1
1
4
4
4
2
2
4
1
5
4
3
5
4
4
3
3
1
1
5
4
2
4
4
4
3
2
2
3
2
3
3
5
4
2
2
2
3
2
3
4
AIBA  BWF 
 
 
FEI 
5
3
4
5
2
5
5
5
5
5
2
FIBA
4
3
3
2
2
5
3
1
2
FIBT
3
3
1
2
5
5
1
1
3
3
FIE
3
5
4
3
5
3
4
5
5
FIFA
5
5
5
5
3
4
4
4
1
5
2
FIG
3
5
3
1
3
3
3
3
3
3
FIH
4
3
3
2
3
3
3
1
3
3
2
1
2
4
2
1
2.80  3.25  4.08 2.70 2.55 3.90 3.92 2.91 2.60
45.0%  56.3%  77.1% 42.5% 38.6% 72.5% 72.9% 47.7% 40.0%
3.13  3.00  3.80 2.56 2.70 3.40 3.10 3.10 2.75
53.1%  50.0%  70.0% 38.9% 42.5% 60.0% 52.5% 52.5% 43.8%
 
 
4
5
5
4
4
5
2
5
4
3
2
2
1
4
4
3
2
2
1
4
2
1
2
1
5
5
4
3
4
2
2
4
2
2
1
5
1
4
4
3
1
4
2.67  3.17  4.50 3.00 2.67 1.83 3.83 2.67 2.83
41.7%  54.2%  87.5% 50.0% 41.7% 20.8% 70.8% 41.7% 45.8%
5
  
64.3%  67.9%
2.86  3.25  4.02
75.0% 39.3%
3.04 3.71 2.81
2.73
46.6%  56.2%  75.6% 43.8% 40.9% 51.1% 67.8% 45.3% 43.2%
Play the Game
112
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0113.png
 
Transparency 
1.1 
1.2 
1.3 
1.4 
1.5 
1.6 
1.7 
1.8 
1.9 
1.10 
1.11 
1.12 
Mean 
Percentage 
Democratic process 
2.1 
2.2 
2.3 
2.4 
2.5 
2.6 
2.7 
2.8 
2.9 
2.10 
Mean 
Percentage 
Checks and balances 
3.1 
3.2 
3.3 
3.4 
3.5 
3.6 
3.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Solidarity 
4.1 
4.2 
4.3 
4.4 
4.5 
4.6 
4.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Total 
SGO index 
FIL 
FINA 
FIS 
FISA
FIVB
IAAF
IBU
ICF
IGF
5
4
5
5
4
5
3
5
3
5
3
4
5
5
3
2
3.92
4
3
4
3
3
5
3
2
2
3
5
4
3
1
3
3
1
2.92
3
5
3
3
5
3
2
1
3
1
2.90
5
1
1
2
2
5
1
3
1
2.33
2.55 
2.80 
4
5
3
3
5
4
3
3
4.08
2
4
2
3
1
2
2.63
5
3
3
3
1
3
3
2
3.00
38.6%  45.0%  77.1% 72.9% 40.6% 50.0% 47.9% 47.5% 33.3%
2.56 
4
4
2
3
2
1
2
2
2
3
3
3
3
1
2
5
3
2
4
2.90
2
5
3
2
3
2
1
3
1
2.44
4
3
3
3
1
3
2
1
3
4
2.70
4
5
2
3
2
1
2
3
1
2
2.50
4
4
2
2
4
1
2
3
3
5
3.00
2
2
1
1
4
1
2
3
2
2.00
2.63 
2
2.40
38.9%  40.6%  35.0% 47.5% 36.1% 42.5% 37.5% 50.0% 25.0%
2.00 
2.83 
2
4
4
3
2
5
3.33
2
4
4
3
2
5
3.33
2
2
4
1
4
2
2
2
2
2.17
1
4
2
4
4
2
2
2.50
4
4
4
3.60
3
1
2
2.20
1
1
2.00
25.0%  45.8%  58.3% 58.3% 37.5% 65.0% 29.2% 30.0% 25.0%
4
5
5
4
4
4
2
4
5
2
2
2
1
2
2.57
3.18
4
2
4
4
4
2
1
1
5
4
3
3
2.57
39.3%
  
  
2.37 
  
2.75 
4.00
3.45
  
75.0% 39.3%
2.52
3.10
2.54
2.70
2.11
34.2%  43.8%  61.4% 54.5% 38.1% 52.5% 38.5% 42.5% 27.8%
Play the Game
113
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0114.png
 
Transparency 
1.1 
1.2 
1.3 
1.4 
1.5 
1.6 
1.7 
1.8 
1.9 
1.10 
1.11 
1.12 
Mean 
Percentage 
Democratic process 
2.1 
2.2 
2.3 
2.4 
2.5 
2.6 
2.7 
2.8 
2.9 
2.10 
Mean 
Percentage 
Checks and balances 
3.1 
3.2 
3.3 
3.4 
3.5 
3.6 
3.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Solidarity 
4.1 
4.2 
4.3 
4.4 
4.5 
4.6 
4.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Total 
SGO index 
IHF 
IIHF 
IJF 
WR
ISAF
ISSF
ISU
ITF
ITTF
3
3
2
1
4
3
3
3
2
2
5
5
1
5
1
2
3.00
3
3
4
3
2
3
3
3
1
2
2
3
2
3
4
3
2
2.58
3
3
2
2
2
1
3
1
3
2
2.20
3
4
3
3
2
5
3
4
5
5
3
2
3.50
2.50 
3.33 
2
5
4
3
1
3
3
2
2.67
2
2
4
2
3
4
2
5
3
2
1
3
3
2
2.88
2.73
37.5%  58.3%  41.7% 50.0% 46.9% 43.2% 39.6% 30.0% 62.5%
2.70 
3.00 
4
4
2
2
3
1
2
1
1
5
2.50
4
5
2
2
4
1
5
2
1
3
2.90
4
5
3
1
3
5
3
4
3.50
4
2
3
2
2
1
2
2
2
4
2.40
4
4
2
2
4
3
2
3
1
2
2.70
4
4
3
2
4
1
5
1
2
2.89
4
4
3
3
1
1
5
4
2
3
3.00
42.5%  50.0%  37.5% 47.5% 62.5% 35.0% 42.5% 47.2% 50.0%
3.60 
3.00 
2
4
2
2
2
2
2.33
2
4
1
2
1
2
2.00
4
4
2
1
2
1
4
4
2
2
2
2.50
2
4
4
2
2
2
2.67
2
4
1
2
1
1
1.83
1
4
3.25
1
2
2
1.67
65.0%  50.0%  33.3% 25.0% 56.3% 16.7% 37.5% 41.7% 20.8%
2
4
1
1
3
3
4
2
3
3
4
4
4
3.43
2.83
3.21
4
4
2
1
1
1
1
3
2
1.57
2.09
4
2
2
1
4
4
3
2.86
2.66
4
4
1
1
1
2
2.17
2.48
4
4
1
1
4
4
3
3.00
2.83
  
  
2.93 
  
3.11 
2
2.29
2.45
  
32.1% 60.7%
14.3% 46.4% 29.2% 50.0%
48.3%  52.8%  36.2% 45.8% 55.2% 27.3% 41.5% 37.0% 45.8%
Play the Game
114
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0115.png
 
Transparency 
1.1 
1.2 
1.3 
1.4 
1.5 
1.6 
1.7 
1.8 
1.9 
1.10 
1.11 
1.12 
Mean 
Percentage 
Democratic process 
2.1 
2.2 
2.3 
2.4 
2.5 
2.6 
2.7 
2.8 
2.9 
2.10 
Mean 
Percentage 
Checks and balances 
3.1 
3.2 
3.3 
3.4 
3.5 
3.6 
3.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Solidarity 
4.1 
4.2 
4.3 
4.4 
4.5 
4.6 
4.7 
Mean 
Percentage 
Total 
SGO index 
IWF 
UCI 
UIPM UWW WA (FITA) WCF
WR
WTF
Mean 
2.82 
3.27 
3
3
3
3
3
3
2
3
1
3
3
3
2.75
4
3
3
3
5
3
1
3
3
2
3.00
3
4
3
3
2
5
4
3
1
3
2
3.00
50.0%
3
3
3
5
1
3
3
3
5
3
3
2
3.08
52.1%
4
3
3
3
2
2
5
5
1
5
1
2
3.00
50.0%
5
3
3
5
1
5
4
3
1
2
2
1
2.92
47.9%
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
2.98 
49.6% 
45.5%  56.8%  43.8% 50.0%
2.60 
2.44 
4
4
2
2
4
1
5
2
2
5
3.10
4
2
2
2
1
2
1
3
3
2.22
4
4
3
2
2
1
2
1
2
5
2.60
40.0%
4
4
2
2
3
3
5
3
3
3
3.20
55.0%
4
5
2
2
4
1
5
2
1
3
2.90
47.5%
5
5
3
2
2
1
5
1
3
2
2.90
47.5%
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
2.81 
45.3% 
40.0%  36.1%  52.5% 30.6%
2.83 
3.00 
2
4
1
1
1
2
1.83
2
4
3
2
2
4
2.83
3
4
2
3
3
2
2.83
45.8%
2
4
1
2
1
2
2.00
25.0%
2
4
1
2
1
2
2.00
25.0%
2
4
4
3
2
2
2.83
45.8%
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
2.66 
41.5% 
45.8%  50.0%  20.8% 45.8%
2.00 
25.0% 
2.56 
3
3
4
3
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
4
2
4
2
3
3
4
4
4
3.43
60.7%
2.83
45.8%
4
2
2
1
1
4
3
2.43
35.7%
2.77
44.2%
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
2.83 
45.7% 
2.82 
45.5% 
4
5
4
5
2
2
2.00
25.0%
  
2.91 
3.71
2.85
2.69
2.81
45.3%
  
67.9%
2.57
39.3%
39.1%  47.6%  46.2% 42.1%
Play the Game
115
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
References 
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1997). The New Economics of corruption: a survey and some new
results.
Political Studies,
45(3), 496-515.
AGGIS group (2013). AGGIS Sports Governance Observer. In J. Alm (Ed.),
Action for Good Gov-
ernance in International Sports Organisations. Final report
(pp. 218-221). Copenhagen: Play the
Game/ Danish Institute for sports studies.
Alm, J. (2013).
Action for Good Governance in International Sports Organisations. Final report.
Co-
penhagen: Play the Game/ Danish Institute for sports studies.
Alt, J., Bueno de Mesquita, E, and Rose, S (2011). Disentangling Accountability and Competence
in Elections: Evidence from U.S. Term Limits.
The Journal of Politics,
73(1), 171–186.
Andreff, W. (2008). Globalisation of the sports economy.
Rivista di diritto ed economia dello sport,
4(3), 13-32.
Andreff, W. and Bourg, J-F. (2006). Broadcasting rights and competition in European football. In
C. Jeanrenaud and S. Késenne, S. (Eds),
The economics of sport and the media
(pp. 37-64), Chelten-
ham: Edward Elgar.
Andreff, W. and Staudohar, P. (2000). The evolving European model of professional sports fi-
nance.
Journal of Sports Economics,
1(3), 257-276.
Arnstein, S.R., (1969). A ladder of citizen participation.
Journal of the American institute of plan-
ners,
35(4), 216-224.
Aucoin, P. and Heintzman, R. (2000). The dialectics of accountability for perfor- mance in public
management reform.
International Review of Administrative Sciences,
66(1), 45–55.
Ball, C. (2009). What Is Transparency?
Public Integrity,
11(4), 293-308.
Banks, J.S. (1989). Agency budgets, cost information and auditing.
American journal of political
science,
33(3), 670-699.
Barker, R. (2003). Legitimacy, legitimation, and the European Union: what crisis? In P. Craig
and R. Rawlings (Eds),
Law and administration in Europe: Essays in honour of Carol Harlow
(pp.
157-174). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Barro, R. (1973). The control of politicians: an economic model.
Public Choice,
14(1), 19–42.
BBC (2015). Fifa: David Cameron backs calls for Sepp Blatter to quit, available at
http://www.bbc.com/news/uk-politics-32913653,
date accessed 16 July 2015.
Beerman, J.M. (2011). A sceptical view of Presidential term limits.
Connecticut law review,
43(4),
1105-1123.
Play the Game
116
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Besley, T. and Case, A. (2003). Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the Unit-
ed States.
Journal of Economic Literature,
41(1), 7–73.
Bovens, M. (2007). Analysing and assessing accountability: a conceptual framework.
European
Law Journal,
13(4), 447–68.
Bovens, M., ‘t Hart, P. and Peters, B.G. (ed.) (2001).
Success and failure in public governance.
Chel-
tenham: Edward Elgar.
Brown, D., Brown, D. and Anastasopoulos, V. (2002).
Women on boards: not just the right thing...
but the “bright” thing.
Ottawa: The conference board of Canada.
BWF (2015). Available at Shuttle Time a Hit at UN Leadership Camp. Available at
http://www.bwfbadminton.org/news_item.aspx?id=95164
Cain, B.E. and Levin, M.A. (1999). Term limits.
Annual Review of Political Science,
2, 163-188.
Calvert, R.L. McCubbins, M.D. and Weingast, B.R. (1989). A theory of political control and
agency discretion.
American Journal of Political Science,
33(3), 588-611.
Carver, J. and Carver, M. (2001). Le modèle Policy Governance et les organismes sans but lucra-
tive.
Gouvernance - revue internationale,
2(1), 30-48.
Chappelet, J-L. (2010).
The autonomy of sport in Europe.
Strasbourg: Council of Europe Publica-
tions.
Chappelet, J-L. and Kübler-Mabott, B. (2008).
The International Olympic Committee and the Olym-
pic system: the governance of world sport.
London: Routledge.
Cherchye, L. Moesen, W. Rogge, N. and Van Puyenbroeck, T. (2006). An introduction to ‘benefit
of the doubt’ composite indicators.
Social Indicators Research,
82(1), 111–145.
Coleman, K.P. (2007).
International Organizations and Peace Enforcement.
Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Cornelissen, S. (2010). The geopolitics of global aspiration: sport mega-events and emerging
powers.
The International Journal of the History of Sport,
27(16-18), 3008-3025.
COSO (Committee of Sponsoring Organizations of the Treadway Commission) (2013). Internal
Control — Integrated Framework. COSO.
Croci, O. and Forster, J. (2004). Webs of authority: hierarchies, networks, legitimacy, and eco-
nomic power in global sport organizations. In G.T. Papanikos (ed.),
The economics and manage-
ment of mega athletic events: Olympic games, professional sports, and other essays
(pp. 3-10). Athens:
Athens Institute for Education and Research.
Play the Game
117
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Cutler, A.C., Haufler, V. and Porter, T. (1999). The contours and significance of private authori-
ty in international affairs. In A.C. Cutler, V. Laufler and T. Porter (Eds),
Private authority and
international affairs
(pp. 333-375). Albany: State University of New York Press.
Dryzek, J.S. (2000).
Deliberative democracy and beyond.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Elgie, R. (2002). The politics of the European Central Bank: principal-agent theory and the dem-
ocratic deficit.
Journal of European Public Policy,
9(2), 186-200.
European Commission (2008). Communication on the Sustainable Consumption and Produc-
tion and Sustainable Industrial Policy Action Plan, COM (2008) 397 final.
European Commission (2011). Commission staff working document, - Impact Assessment ac-
companying document to the Communication “Developing the European Dimension in Sport”.
SEC (2011) 67 final.
European Parliament (2013). Resolution on match-fixing and corruption in sport,
2013/2567(RSP).
European Parliament (2015) Resolution on recent revelations of high-level corruption cases in
FIFA, P8_TA-PROV(2015)0233.
Eurostrategies, Amnyos, CDES, & Deutsche Sporthochschule Köln (2011).
Study on the funding of
grassroots sports in the EU with a focus on the internal market aspects concerning legislative frameworks
and systems of financing
(Eurostrategies Final report No. 1). Available at
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/top_layer/docs/Executive-summary_en.pdf
Fearon, J.D. (1999). Electoral accountability and the control of politicians: Selecting good types
versus sanctioning poor performance. In A. Przeworski, S.C. Stokes and B. Manin (Eds),
Democ-
racy, accountability, and representation
(pp. 55–97), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.
Public Choice,
50(1–3), 5–26.
Fondas, N. and Sassalos, S. (2000). A different voice in the boardroom: How the presence of
women directors affects board influence over management.
Global focus,
12(2), 13–22.
Forster, J. and Pope, N. (2004).
The political economy of global sporting organisations.
London:
Routledge.
Fox, C.J. and Miller, H.T. (1995).
Postmodern public administration.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Frost, M. (2013). Legitimacy and international organizations: the changing ethical context. In D.
Zaum (Ed.),
Legitimating international organizations
(pp. pp. 26-40). Oxford: Oxford University
Press,
García, B. (2007). UEFA and the European Union: from confrontation to co-operation?
Journal of
Contemporary European Research,
3(3), 202-223.
Play the Game
118
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
García, B. and Weatherill, S. (2012). Engaging with the EU in order to minimize its impact: sport
and the negotiation of the Treaty of Lisbon.
Journal of European Public Policy,
19(2), 238-256.
Geeraert, A. (2015). Indicators and benchmarking tools for sports governance. In: Transparency
International (Ed),
Global corruption report: corruption in sport.
London: Routledge.
Geeraert, A. (2016a). The governance of international sport organisations. In … Sport and Socie-
ty, London: Sage
Geeraert, A. (2016b). The European Union in International Sports Governance. London: Pal-
grave Macmillan.
Geeraert, A. (2016c). Theorising the governance of sport mega-events: a principal-agent per-
spective. In: Frawley S. (Eds.),
Managing Sport Mega-Events.
London: Routledge.
Geeraert A, and Drieskens, E. (2015a). The EU controls FIFA and UEFA: a principal-agent per-
spective.
Journal of European Public Policy,
22(10), 1448-1466.
Geeraert, A. and Drieskens, E. (2015b). Theorizing the EU and international sport: the principal-
agent model and beyond,
Sport & EU Review,
7(1), 6-22.
Geeraert, A. Mrkonjic, M. and Chappelet, J.L. (2014). A rationalist perspective on the autonomy
of international sport governing bodies: towards a pragmatic autonomy in the steering of
sports.
International Journal of Sport Policy and Politics,
doi: 10.1080/19406940.2014.925953
Geeraert, A., Alm, J., Groll, M. (2014). Good Governance in International Sport Organisations:
an Analysis of the 35 Olympic Sport Governing Bodies.
International Journal of Sport Policy and
Politics,
6 (3), 281–306
Gibson, O. (2015). Fifa officials arrested on corruption charges as World Cup inquiry launched,
The Guardian
27 May, http://www.theguardian.com/football/2015/may/27/several-top-fifa-
officials-arrested,
date accessed 8 June 2015.
Glazer, A. and Wattenberg, M. (1996). Promoting Legislative Work: A Case for Term Limits. In
B. Grofman (Ed.),
Legislative Term Limits: Public Choice Perspective.
Boston: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Hartmann, G. (2013). IWF president under suspicion of financial mismanagement. Available at
http://www.playthegame.org/news/news-articles/2013/iwf-president-under-suspicion-of-
financial-mismanagement/
Henry, I. and Lee, P.C. (2004). Governance and ethics in sport. In S. Chadwick and J. Beech
(eds.),
The business of sport management
(pp. 25-42). Harlow: Pearson Education.
Héritier, A. and Lehmkuhl, D. (2011). Governing in the shadow of hierarchy: new modes of
governance in regulation. In A. Héritier and M. Rhodes (eds.),
New modes of governance in Eu-
Play the Game
119
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
rope. Governing in the shadow of hierarchy
(pp. 48-74). Basingstoke and New York: Palgrave Mac-
millan.
Holt, M. (2006).
UEFA, governance and the control of club competition in European football.
London:
Birbeck Sport Business Centre.
Hopkins, M. (1991). Human Development Revisited: A New UNDP Report.
World Development,
19(10), 1469–1473.
Hoy, M. (2005). Volleygate: a showcase of greed and mismanagement.
Play The Game Magazine,
3, 14-15.
Houlihan, B. (1999). Anti-doping policy in sport: the politics of international policy co-
ordination.
Public Administration,
77(2), 311-334.
Houlihan, B. (2001). The World Anti-Doping Agency: Prospects for Success. In J. O’Leary (ed.),
Drugs and Doping in Sport: Socio-Legal Perspectives
(pp. 125–45). London: Cavendish.
Hurd, I. (2002). Legitimacy, power, and the symbolic life of the UN Security Council.
Global
Governance,
8(1), 35-51.
IAAF (2015) Athletics for a better world and United Nations development programme cement
partnership in Bejing. Available at http://www.iaaf.org/news/iaaf-news/beijing-2015-abw-
undp
Independent Governance Committee (2014). FIFA governance reform project. Second report by
the independent governance committee to the executive committee of FIFA (February 6, 2013).
In M. Pieth (ed.),
Reforming FIFA
(pp. 91-102). Zürich: Dike Verlag.
International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) (2008).
Combating Extortion and Bribery: ICC Rules of
Conduct and Recommendations.
Paris: International Chamber of Commerce.
IIA (2013). International standards for the professional practice of internal auditing. Available
at: http://www.theiia.org/guidance/standards-and-guidance/ippf/standards/full-
standards/?search=risk.
IOC (2008)
Position of the Olympic and sports movement on the specificity and autonomy of sport.
Lau-
sanne: IOC.
IOC (2010). UN and sports federations team up to score for development. Available at
http://www.un.org/apps/news/story.asp?NewsID=34549#.Vfm46Xg0wU4
IOC (2011) United Nations and International Volleyball Federation partner for change. Availa-
ble at http://www.sportanddev.org/?3783/United-Nations-and-International-Volleyball-
Federation-Join-Forces-to-Drive-Social-Change
IOC (2012) The United Nations and the International Judo Federation Sign Partnership to Rein-
force their Cooperation. Available at
Play the Game
120
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
http://www.un.org/wcm/content/site/sport/home/newsandevents/news/template/news_i
tem.jsp?cid=36910
IOC (2013a). The United Nations and the International Bobsleigh and Skeleton Federation Sign
MOU to support a future partnership. Available at
http://www.un.org/wcm/content/site/sport/home/sport/template/news_item.jsp?cid=4081
3
IOC (2013b).
Olympic Charter.
Lausanne: IOC.
IOC (2014). IOC and UN Secretariat agree historic deal to work together to use sport to build a
better world. Available at http://www.olympic.org/news/ioc-and-un-secretariat-agree-
historic-deal/230542.
Jackson, S.J. and Haigh, S. (eds) (2009).
Sport and foreign policy in a globalizing world.
London:
Routledge.
Jennings, A. (2006).
Foul! The secret world of FIFA: bribes, vote-rigging and ticket scandals.
London:
HarperCollins.
Katwala, S. (2000).
Democratising global sport.
London: The foreign policy centre.
Kaufmann, D. and Kraay, A. (2008). Governance Indicators: Where Are We, Where Should We
Be Going?
The World Bank Research Observer,
23(1), 1-30.
Kędzior, M. and Szczepanik, M. (2011). Poland: new shape, old problems. In A. Niemann, B.
García, and W. Grant (eds.),
The transformation of European football: towards the Europeanisation of
the national game
(pp. 204-219). Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Kiewiet, D.R. and McCubbins, M.D. (1991).
The logic of delegation: congressional parties and the
appropriations process.
Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Klijn, E.-H. and Koppenjan, J.F.M. (2004).
Managing Uncertainties in Networks.
London:
Routledge
Lindgreen, A., Swaen, V. and Johnston, W.J. (2009). Corporate social responsibility: An empiri-
cal investigation of U.S. organizations.
Journal of business ethics,
85(2), 303–323.
Lindseth, P. (2004)
Agents without principals? Delegation in an age of diffuse and fragmented govern-
ance
(University of Connecticut School of Law Articles and Working Papers, Paper 18).
Lipton, M. and Lorsch, J. (1992). A modest proposal for improved corporate governance.
Busi-
ness lawyer,
48(1), 59-77.
Majone, G. (1999). The regulatory state and its legitimacy problems.
West European Politics,
22(1),
1-24.
Play the Game
121
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Mallon, B. (2000). The Olympic bribery scandal.
The journal of Olympic History,
8(2), 11-27.
Maltz, G. (2007). The case for Presidential term limits.
Journal of Democracy,
18(1), 128-142.
McCubbins, M.D. and Page, T. (1987). A theory of congressional delegation. In M.D. McCubbins
and T. Sullivan (eds.),
Congress: structure and policy
(pp. 404-425), Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press.
McCubbins, M.D. and Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: police patrols
versus fire alarms.
American Journal of Political Science,
28(1), 165-179.
McCubbins, M.D. Noll, R.G. and Weingast, B.R. (1989). Structure and process, politics and poli-
cy: administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies.
Virginia Law Review,
75(2),
431-482.
Mouffe, C. (1993).
The Return of the Political.
London: Verso.
Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., and Tarantola, S. (2005).
Tools for Composite Indicators Build-
ing.
Ispra: Institute for the Protection and Security of the Citizen, Econometrics and Statistical
Support to Antifraud Unit (European Commission).
Newman, J., (2005). Participative governance and the remaking of the public sphere. In J. New-
man (Ed.),
Remaking governance: peoples, politics and the public sphere
(119–138.). Cambridge: Poli-
ty Press.
Nielson, D.L. and Tierney, M.J. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: agency theory
and World Bank environmental reform.
International Organization,
57(2), 241-276.
Parliamentary assembly of the Council of Europe (2012).
Good governance and ethics in sport.
Res-
olution 1875 (2012) Final.
Parrish, R. (2003).
Sports law and policy in the European Union.
Manchester: Manchester Universi-
ty Press.
Parrish, R. and McArdle, D. (2004). Beyond Bosman: the European Union's influence upon pro-
fessional athletes' freedom of movement.
Sport in Society,
7(3), 403-419.
Pass, C. (2004). Corporate governance and the role of non-executive directors in large UK com-
panies: an empirical study.
Corporate Governance: The international journal of business in society,
(4)2, 52-63.
Pieth, M. (2011).
Governing FIFA, concept paper and report.
Basel: Universität Basel.
Pieth, M. (ed.) (2014a).
Reforming FIFA.
Zürich: Dike Verlag.
Pieth, M. (2014b). Introduction: governing FIFA. In Pieth, M. (ed.),
Reforming FIFA
(pp. 7-16)
Zürich: Dike Verlag.
Play the Game
122
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Pollack, M.A. (1997). Delegation, agency, and agenda setting in the European Community.
In-
ternational Organization,
57(1), 99-134.
Pollack, M.A. (2003).
The engines of European integration. Delegation, Agency, and Agenda Setting in
the EU.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Randall, D. and Brady, B. (2011). Fifa accused promises 'tsunami' of revelations at bribery hear-
ing. The Independent,
http://www.independent.co.uk/sport/football/news-and-comment/fifa-accused-
promises-tsunami-of-revelations-at-bribery-hearing-2290579.html,
date accessed 11 July 2015.
Reus-Smit, C. (2007). International crises of legitimacy.
International politics,
44(2), 157–174.
Saward, M. (2005). Governance and the transformation of political representation. In J. Newman
(ed.),
Remaking governance: peoples, politics and the public sphere
(pp. 179–193). Cambridge, MA:
Policy Press.
Snidal, D. (1985). The game theory of international politics.
World Politics,
38(1), 25-57.
Sørensen, E. and Torfing, J. (2009). Making governance networks effective and democratic
through metagovernance.
Public Administration,
87(2): 234–58.
Rossing, D. (2014). Skater’s Lawsuit May End Sports Bodies’ Grip on Competion. Available at
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-12-02/skater-s-lawsuit-may-end-sports-
bodies-grip-on-competion
Saalfeld, T. (2000). Members of parliament and governments in Western Europe: Agency rela-
tions and problems of oversight.
European Journal of Political Research
37(3), 353–376
.
Schenk, S. (2011).
Safe hands: building integrity and transparency at FIFA.
Berlin: Transparency
International.
Sealy, R.H.V. and Singh, V. (2010). The importance of role models and demographic context for
senior women's work identity development.
International Journal of Management Reviews,
12(3),
284-300.
Smart, M. and Sturm, D.M. (2013). Term limits and electoral accountability.
Journal of public
economics,
107, 93-102.
Strøm, K. (2000). Delegation and accountability in parliamentary democracies.
European Journal
of Political Research,
37(3), 261-289.
Sugden, J. and Tomlinson, A. (1998).
FIFA and the contest for world football: who rules the peoples’
game?
Cambridge: Polity Press.
Sutchman, M. (1995). Managing legitimacy: strategic and institutional approaches.
Academy of
Management Review,
20(3), 571-610.
Play the Game
123
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Szymanski, S. (2006). A theory on the evolution of modern sport (International association of
sports economists Working Paper Series, No. 06-30),
http://college.holycross.edu/RePEc/spe/Szymanski_Evolution.pdf, date accessed 8 June 2015.
Tabarrok, A. (1994). A survey, critique, and new defense of term limits.
Cato Journal
14(2), 333-
350.
Terjesen, S., Sealy, R. and Singh, V. (2009). Women directors on corporate boards: a review and
research agenda.
Corporate governance: an international review,
17(3), 320-337.
Thibault, L., Kihl, L. and Babiak, K. (2010). Democratization and governance in international
sport: addressing issues with athlete involvement in organizational policy.
International Journal
of Sport Policy and Politics,
2(3), 275-302.
Tomlinson, A. (2005). The making of the global sports economy: ISL, the rise of the corporate
player in world sport. In M.L. Silk, D.L. Andrews and C.L. Cole (Eds),
Sport and corporate nation-
alisms
(pp. 35-66). Oxford: Berg.
TOROC (2006). Guidance document on the implementation of EMAS in sporting events, availa-
ble at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/emas/pdf/guidance/guidance09_en.pdf.
UCI (2015). The UCI approves key principles for the reform of men’s professional road cycling,
available at http://www.uci.ch/pressreleases/the-uci-approves-key-principles-for-the-reform-
men-professional-road-cycling/
UK Parliament (2011).
Culture, media and sport committee - sixth report 2018 World Cup bid.
Lon-
don: UK Parliament.
UNESCO (2015). Partners. Available at http://www.unesco.org/new/en/social-and-human-
sciences/themes/physical-education-and-sport/partners/
Vafeas, N. (1999). Board meeting frequency and firm performance.
Journal of Financial Economics,
53(1), 113-142.
Vaubel, R. (2006). Principal-agent problems in international organizations.
Review of Internation-
al Organizations,
1(2), 125–138.
Vocasport (2004).
La formation dans le domaine du sport en Europe.
Lyon: European observatoire of
sport and employment.
Voy, R.O. and Deeter, K.D. (1991).
Drugs, sport, and politics.
Champaign: Leisure Press.
Walters, G. (2011). Bidding for international sport events: how government supports and un-
dermines national governing bodies of sport.
Sport in Society,
14(2), 208-222.
Watts, P. and Holme, R. (1999).
Meeting changing expectations. Corporate social responsibility.
Ge-
neva: WBCSD.
Play the Game
124
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
Weinreich, J. (2014a).
Macht, Moneten, Marionetten: Ein Wegweiser durch die Olympische Parallelge-
sellschaft. IOC, FIFA, Bach, Putin, Blatter, Scheichs und Oligarchen.
Berlin: Krautreporter.
Weinreich, J. (2014b).
2022 Die WM in Katar, Sklavenarbeit, Korruption und die FIFA.
Berlin:
Krautreporter.
Welsh, J. and Zaum, D. (2013).Legitimation and the UN Security Council. In D. Zaum (ed.),
Legitimating international organizations
(pp. 65-87). Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Williams, P. D. (2013). Regional and global legitimacy dynamics: The United Nations and re-
gional arrangements. In D. Zaum (ed.),
Legitimating international organizations
(pp. 41-62). Ox-
ford: Oxford University Press.
Woods, N. (1999). Good Governance in international organisations.
Global Governance,
5(1), 39–
61.
Young, I. (2000).
Inclusion and democracy.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zaum, D. (2013). International Organizations, Legitimacy, and Legitimation. In D. Zaum (Ed.),
Legitimating international organizations
(pp. 3-25). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zelechowski, D. and Bilimoria, D. (2004). Characteristics of women and men corporate inside
directors in the US.
Corporate governance: an international review,
12(3), 337–42.
Play the Game
125
 www.playthegame.org
KUU, Alm.del - 2015-16 - Bilag 48: Pressemeddelelse og rapporten ’Sports Governance Observer’
1576773_0126.png